Knowledge

Penn effect

Source đź“ť

219:(CPI) show the same pattern; equivalent things tend to cost more in high income countries. Most services, perishable goods like the Big Mac, and housing cannot be purchased very far from the point of consumption (where the consumer happens to live). These items form the typical consumer shopping list, and therefore the consumer price level can vary from country to country, just like the burger price. 99:, with studies since then consistently confirming the original Penn effect. However, subsequent analysis has provided many other mechanisms through which the Penn effect can arise, and historical cases where it is expected, but not found. Up until 1994 the PPP-deviation tended to be known as the "Balassa-Samuelson effect", but in his review of progress "Facets of Balassa-Samuelson Thirty Years Later" 239:
level in the rich world. If the money income levels are taken as given, then all else being equal, the Penn effect is beneficial. If it did not apply, millions of the world's poorest people would find that their income was below the survival threshold. However, the effect implies that the money
170:
model treating Big Macs as commodity goods implies that international price competition will force Norwegian, Egyptian, and U.S. burger prices to converge in price. The Penn effect, however, maintains that the general price level will remain consistently higher where (dollar) incomes are high.
381:
study finds that industrialized countries tend to fit Cassel's hypothesis better (at a ratio of 2 countries to 1). This result can occur (despite an apparently clear correlation of income to price) because of the long reversion times expected by the PPP
73:(PPP) hypothesis, also expressed as saying that the real exchange rate (RER) between goods in various countries should be close to one. Fluctuations over time were expected by this theory but were predicted to be small and non-systematic. 251:
between rich and poor countries is less than GDP per capita figures would suggest, if converted at market exchange rates. To make a more significant comparison, economists divide a country's average income by its consumer price index.
183:
says that the same item cannot sustain two different sale prices in the same market (since everyone would buy only at the lower price). By reversing this law, we can infer that different countries do not share an
64:
Classical economics made simple predictions about exchange rates; it was said that a basket of goods would cost roughly the same amount everywhere in the world, when paid for in some common currency (like
377:- A direct 2003 comparison of Cassel's pure PPP-hypothesis and the Penn effect deviation at scales estimated by the BS-hypothesis (using data from sixteen industrialized countries). Surprisingly, this 207:
burgers the price in Oslo will be unaffected, since one is unlikely to dine in Cairo if starting the evening in Oslo, nor can one import an Egyptian meal into Norway by ordering take-out.
199:
restaurant at one quarter the price they would do so, and price competition would then equalize the Big Mac price throughout the world. Of course, someone can only eat out
53:
However, the "Penn effect", even as Samuelson used it, refers to the general observation: there is correlation between higher price levels and higher per capita income.
88:
team documented a modern relationship: countries with higher incomes consistently had higher prices of domestically produced goods (as measured by comparable
354:(their time series starts 1500 AD, with the Penn effect only noticeable 450 years into the data). The appendix contains a thorough (eight page) two country 369: 247:
If the genuine income differential (taking local prices into account) is exaggerated by the market exchange rate, so the real difference in the
362:
across a continuum of industries, endogenously split between traded and non-traded production. However, the paper as a whole is focused on
56:
The Balassa-Samuelson effect model arises from a project to confirm the result and explicate the cause within the neoclassical framework.
203:, so regional price differentials can persist; the Oslo and Cairo branches are not in competition. If the Cairo McDonald's starts 240:
income level disparity as measured by international exchange rates is an illusion, because these exchange rates only apply to
374: 104: 107:
data-gatherers, by coining the term "Penn effect" to describe the "basic fact" they uncovered, when he wrote:
400: 359: 308:. It was thought that deviations from this would mostly be caused by problems of supply, and the fact that 96: 370:
G-20 ICP: An analysis of the data in the International Comparison Program gives clear Penn effect examples
174: 395: 85: 274: 228: 163: 138:" country will usually find their money going a lot further abroad than at home. For instance, a 70: 313: 185: 35: 351: 215:
Measuring 'the' price level involves looking at goods other than burgers, but most goods in a
378: 154:
for those two local currencies, despite the fact the two products are essentially the same.
321: 288:
For instance, economists in 1949 expected that one could buy similar quantities of meat in
216: 130:
Most things are cheaper in poor (low income) countries than in rich ones. Someone from a "
8: 355: 338: 248: 175:
How identical products can be sold at consistently different prices in different places
180: 81: 43: 305: 115:
is an important phenomenon of actual history, but not an inevitable fact of life.
166:
hypothesis argues that the Balassa–Samuelson effect should not occur. A simple
100: 39: 389: 317: 309: 289: 268: 262: 151: 139: 125: 333:
Paul A. Samuelson (1994). "Facets of Balassa-Samuelson Thirty Years Later,"
167: 27:
finding that commodity prices are higher in countries with higher income.
363: 236: 200: 188:
common market from the fact that prices for the same good are different.
135: 131: 77: 47: 157: 241: 34:
ratios between high and low income countries are misrepresented by
24: 95:
In 1964 the modern theoretical interpretation was set down as the
271:
consistently shows fourfold differentials in the burger's price.
143: 31: 375:
Long Run Purchasing Power Parity: Cassel or Balassa-Samuelson?
352:
2004 Econometric study of the effect's rise since circa 1950
297: 232: 222: 196: 147: 192: 66: 341:. (This issue has several papers discussing the effect.) 301: 293: 89: 277:
is the situation in which RERs are 1, a nil Penn effect.
158:
The effect's challenge to simple open economy models
103:acknowledged the debt that his theory owed to the 387: 119: 358:derivation of the effect's size based on the 30:This is often interpreted to mean that real 235:to survive on an income below the absolute 92:), when compared at market exchange rates. 223:The international development implications 316:to market levels by most of the world's 42:. It is associated with what became the 150:in January 2013, at the prevailing USD 388: 320:(before the 1970s and the end of the 244:, a small proportion of consumption. 364:analysis of historical economic data 339:(Abstract defining the Penn effect) 76:Pre-1940, the PPP hypothesis found 13: 210: 14: 412: 345: 335:Review of International Economics 306:nominal exchange rate at the time 195:were able to eat in an identical 80:support, but some time after the 50:result since at least the 1950s. 16:Observed phenomenon in economics 286: 46:, and it has been a consistent 1: 327: 324:era of gold convertibility). 120:Understanding the Penn effect 281: 134:" country on vacation in a " 7: 255: 84:, a series of studies by a 38:(GDP) conversion at market 10: 417: 191:If a McDonald's patron in 123: 86:University of Pennsylvania 59: 162:The (naĂŻve form of the) 97:Balassa–Samuelson effect 337:2(3), pp. 201–26. 275:Purchasing Power Parity 229:Purchasing power parity 164:purchasing power parity 71:purchasing power parity 117: 69:). This is called the 36:gross domestic product 379:University of Houston 124:Further information: 109: 401:Eponyms in economics 312:were not allowed to 217:consumer price index 356:General equilibrium 249:standard of living 396:Economics effects 227:The deviation in 105:Penn World Tables 408: 181:law of one price 82:Second World War 44:Penn World Table 416: 415: 411: 410: 409: 407: 406: 405: 386: 385: 348: 330: 284: 258: 225: 213: 211:The price level 177: 160: 142:cost $ 7.84 in 128: 122: 62: 17: 12: 11: 5: 414: 404: 403: 398: 384: 383: 372: 367: 347: 346:External links 344: 343: 342: 329: 326: 310:exchange rates 283: 280: 279: 278: 272: 257: 254: 224: 221: 212: 209: 176: 173: 159: 156: 146:and $ 2.39 in 121: 118: 101:Paul Samuelson 61: 58: 40:exchange rates 15: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 413: 402: 399: 397: 394: 393: 391: 380: 376: 373: 371: 368: 365: 361: 360:BS hypothesis 357: 353: 350: 349: 340: 336: 332: 331: 325: 323: 322:Bretton Woods 319: 318:central banks 315: 311: 307: 304:, the pegged 303: 299: 295: 291: 287: 276: 273: 270: 269:Big Mac Index 266: 264: 263:The Economist 260: 259: 253: 250: 245: 243: 238: 234: 231:allows rural 230: 220: 218: 208: 206: 202: 198: 194: 189: 187: 182: 172: 169: 165: 155: 153: 152:exchange rate 149: 145: 141: 137: 133: 127: 126:Big Mac Index 116: 114: 108: 106: 102: 98: 93: 91: 90:price indices 87: 83: 79: 74: 72: 68: 57: 54: 51: 49: 45: 41: 37: 33: 28: 26: 22: 334: 285: 261: 246: 242:traded goods 226: 214: 204: 190: 178: 168:open economy 161: 129: 112: 110: 94: 75: 63: 55: 52: 29: 20: 18: 382:hypothesis. 237:subsistence 205:giving away 136:third world 132:first world 113:Penn effect 78:econometric 48:econometric 21:Penn effect 390:Categories 328:References 282:Footnotes 186:efficient 300:for 360 292:for one 290:New York 256:See also 25:economic 233:Indians 201:locally 140:Big Mac 60:History 23:is the 296:as in 294:dollar 144:Norway 32:income 314:float 298:Tokyo 197:Cairo 148:Egypt 193:Oslo 179:The 111:The 67:gold 19:The 302:Yen 392:: 267:s 366:. 265:'

Index

economic
income
gross domestic product
exchange rates
Penn World Table
econometric
gold
purchasing power parity
econometric
Second World War
University of Pennsylvania
price indices
Balassa–Samuelson effect
Paul Samuelson
Penn World Tables
Big Mac Index
first world
third world
Big Mac
Norway
Egypt
exchange rate
purchasing power parity
open economy
law of one price
efficient
Oslo
Cairo
locally
consumer price index

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑