Knowledge

Contestable market

Source đź“ť

186:
enter the market, which would lead to higher competition and thus lower prices. That would make the market more contestable. Sunk costs are those costs that cannot be recovered after a firm shuts down. For example, if a new firm enters the steel industry, the entrant needs to buy new machinery. If, for any reason, the new firm cannot cope with the competition of the incumbent firm, it will plan to move out of the market. However, if the new firm cannot use or transfer the new machines that it bought for the production of steel to other uses in another industry, the fixed costs on machinery become sunk costs so if there are sunk costs in the market, they impede the first assumption of no exit barriers. That market will not be contestable, and no firms would enter the steel industry.
249:. More generally, experimental evidence collected since the publication of Baumol's paper has suggested that perfectly competitive markets would, if they existed, behave in the way Baumol outlined, but the performance of imperfectly contestable markets (i.e. real-world markets) depends "on actual rather than potential competition" perhaps in part due to the range of "strategic responses" available to incumbents that were not considered by Baumol as part of his theory. 36: 218:, potential rivals will enter the market, hoping to exploit the high price for easy profit. When the original incumbent firm(s) respond by returning prices to levels consistent with normal profits, the new firms will exit. Because of that, even a single-firm market can show highly competitive behavior. 338:
Brock, 1983. p.1063, quoting Baumol, 1982: "This means that... an incumbent, even if he can threaten retaliation after entry, dare not offer profit-making opportunities to potential entrants because an entering firm can hit and run, gathering in the available profits and departing when the going gets
244:
and entry and exit barriers. Low-cost airlines remain a commonly referenced example of a contestable market; entrants have the possibility of leasing aircraft and should be able to respond to high profits by quickly entering and exiting. However, it is now generally admitted that Baumol's judgment
185:
Thus, for example, a monopoly protected by high barriers to entry (for example, it owns all the strategic resources) will make supernormal or abnormal profits with no fear of competition. However, in the same case, if it did not own the strategic resources for production, other firms could easily
194:
in the form of lower average cost of production. A new firm entering the market, with insufficient information or technology, could incur a higher average cost of production and so be unable to compete with the incumbent firm. That would lead to the incumbent firm enjoying monopoly power and
189:
It is very important for firms to have access to the same level of technology as that helps determine the average cost of the product. An incumbent firm having more knowledge and access to a technology for the production of a commodity could enjoy higher
357:
Brock, 1983. p. 1064. "Baumol et al.'s plea for removal of artificial barriers to entry and exit is to be applauded.... I am more skeptical about their conclusions that occasionally it is good public policy to restrict entry and
177:
A perfectly contestable market is not possible in real life. Instead, the degree of contestability of a market is talked about. The more contestable a market is, the closer it will be to a perfectly contestable market.
195:
supernormal profit in the market, as the new firm will exit the market. A solution to the problem could be governments providing equal access to knowledge and technology, as well as financial resources for the same.
433: 181:
Some economists argue that determining price and output is actually dependent not on the type of market structure (whether it is a monopoly or perfectly competitive market) but on the threat of competition.
245:
that the US airline industry was therefore best left deregulated was incorrect since the now duly deregulated industry is "well on its way" to evolving into a concentrated
240:
The applicability of the theory to real-world situations may be questioned, however, particularly as there are very few markets which are completely free of
237:
to control the price level. Baumol himself argued based on the theory for both deregulation in certain industries and for more regulation in others.
206:; in theory, a perfectly contestable market would have no barriers to entry or exit ("frictionless reversible entry" in economist 416: 100: 367:
Brock, 1983. p. 1057. "Some readers may feel that perfect contestability is an idealized notion of purely academic interest..."
72: 439:(arguing against the existence of anti-trust laws based on theory that government is solely responsible for coercive monopoly) 148:
served by a small number of firms that are nevertheless characterized by competitive equilibrium (and therefore desirable
79: 53: 456: 327: 119: 86: 310: 68: 57: 17: 471: 258: 221:
A concise theoretical statement of contestable markets with an illustrative graph is at Economics Online.
476: 444: 268: 46: 93: 8: 273: 211: 191: 145: 452: 323: 263: 199: 149: 141: 233:, as simply observing a monopoly market may not prove that a firm is exploiting its 210:'s terms). Contestable markets are characterized by "hit and run" competition; if a 229:
The theory of contestable markets has been used to argue for weaker application of
207: 203: 230: 423: 392: 465: 215: 173:
Access to the same level of technology (to incumbent firms and new entrants)
234: 404:
Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure: A Review Article
403: 241: 168: 246: 133: 35: 214:
in a contestable market raises its prices so as to begin to earn
152:) because of the existence of potential short-term entrants. 397:
Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure
160:
A perfectly contestable market has three main features:
413:
John C. Panzar (1987). "Competition and efficiency,"
322:
Essentials of Economics, John Sloman (third edition)
451:Essentials of Economics, John Sloman (3rd edition) 395:, John C. Panzar, & Robert D. Willig (1982). 60:. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. 313:, Economics Online (at www.economicsonline.co.uk). 463: 140:, associated primarily with its 1982 proponent 428:The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics 293: 291: 289: 375: 373: 120:Learn how and when to remove this message 286: 417:New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics 370: 14: 464: 305: 303: 58:adding citations to reliable sources 29: 410:, v. 91, no. 6, pp. 1055–1066. 24: 25: 488: 445:The Theory of Contestable Markets 300: 198:Its fundamental features are low 408:The Journal of Political Economy 34: 45:needs additional citations for 361: 351: 342: 332: 316: 224: 13: 1: 386: 348:For example, Greenspan, 1998. 7: 252: 10: 493: 402:William A. Brock (1983). " 164:No entry or exit barriers 155: 430:, v. 1, pp. 531–46. 420:, v. 1, pp. 543–44. 279: 269:Monopolistic competition 259:Bertrand–Edgeworth model 442:Stephen Martin (2000). 426:(1987). "Competition," 311:"Contestable markets" 144:, held that there are 472:Monopoly (economics) 379:Martin, 2000. p. 43. 309:Critic Capital LLC, 297:Brock, 1983. p.1055. 69:"Contestable market" 54:improve this article 274:Perfect competition 138:contestable markets 27:Theory in economics 477:Market (economics) 192:economies of scale 437:by Alan Greenspan 424:George J. Stigler 393:William J. Baumol 264:Coercive monopoly 200:barriers to entry 142:William J. Baumol 130: 129: 122: 104: 16:(Redirected from 484: 380: 377: 368: 365: 359: 355: 349: 346: 340: 336: 330: 320: 314: 307: 298: 295: 150:welfare outcomes 136:, the theory of 125: 118: 114: 111: 105: 103: 62: 38: 30: 21: 492: 491: 487: 486: 485: 483: 482: 481: 462: 461: 389: 384: 383: 378: 371: 366: 362: 356: 352: 347: 343: 337: 333: 321: 317: 308: 301: 296: 287: 282: 255: 227: 158: 126: 115: 109: 106: 63: 61: 51: 39: 28: 23: 22: 15: 12: 11: 5: 490: 480: 479: 474: 460: 459: 449: 440: 431: 421: 411: 400: 388: 385: 382: 381: 369: 360: 350: 341: 331: 315: 299: 284: 283: 281: 278: 277: 276: 271: 266: 261: 254: 251: 231:antitrust laws 226: 223: 216:excess profits 175: 174: 171: 165: 157: 154: 128: 127: 42: 40: 33: 26: 18:Contestability 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 489: 478: 475: 473: 470: 469: 467: 458: 457:0-273-68382-9 454: 450: 447: 446: 441: 438: 436: 432: 429: 425: 422: 419: 418: 412: 409: 405: 401: 398: 394: 391: 390: 376: 374: 364: 358:competition." 354: 345: 335: 329: 328:0-273-68382-9 325: 319: 312: 306: 304: 294: 292: 290: 285: 275: 272: 270: 267: 265: 262: 260: 257: 256: 250: 248: 243: 238: 236: 232: 222: 219: 217: 213: 209: 208:William Brock 205: 201: 196: 193: 187: 183: 179: 172: 170: 166: 163: 162: 161: 153: 151: 147: 143: 139: 135: 124: 121: 113: 102: 99: 95: 92: 88: 85: 81: 78: 74: 71: â€“  70: 66: 65:Find sources: 59: 55: 49: 48: 43:This article 41: 37: 32: 31: 19: 443: 434: 427: 414: 407: 396: 363: 353: 344: 334: 318: 239: 235:market power 228: 220: 197: 188: 184: 180: 176: 159: 137: 131: 116: 107: 97: 90: 83: 76: 64: 52:Please help 47:verification 44: 225:Application 466:Categories 387:References 242:sunk costs 169:sunk costs 110:April 2020 80:newspapers 435:Antitrust 247:oligopoly 134:economics 253:See also 339:rough." 146:markets 94:scholar 455:  326:  156:Theory 96:  89:  82:  75:  67:  280:Notes 101:JSTOR 87:books 453:ISBN 415:The 324:ISBN 212:firm 204:exit 202:and 73:news 406:". 167:No 132:In 56:by 468:: 372:^ 302:^ 288:^ 448:. 399:. 123:) 117:( 112:) 108:( 98:· 91:· 84:· 77:· 50:. 20:)

Index

Contestability

verification
improve this article
adding citations to reliable sources
"Contestable market"
news
newspapers
books
scholar
JSTOR
Learn how and when to remove this message
economics
William J. Baumol
markets
welfare outcomes
sunk costs
economies of scale
barriers to entry
exit
William Brock
firm
excess profits
antitrust laws
market power
sunk costs
oligopoly
Bertrand–Edgeworth model
Coercive monopoly
Monopolistic competition

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑