Knowledge

Total revenue

Source 📝

53: 321: 309: 297: 64: 39:. That is, there is exactly one price that it can sell at – the market price. At any lower price it could get more revenue by selling the same amount at the market price, while at any higher price no one would buy any quantity. Total revenue equals the market price times the quantity the firm chooses to produce and sell. 338:
The function of TR is graphed as a downward opening parabola due to the concept of elasticity of demand. When price goes up, quantity will go down. Whether the total revenue will grow or drop depends on the original price and quantity and the slope of the demand curve. For example, total revenue will
288:, which is a quadratic. In Figures 2 through 4, this function is shown graphically by using an example of demand for apples. The quantity of apples demanded drops as the price increases, which leads to the changes of the total revenue. 403:, a similar rule also can be applied when a firm needs to decide whether it should enter or exit a market. Here physical capital costs are relevant, and together with variable costs they give total long-run costs (TC): 371:
Rational people and firms are assumed to make the most profitable decision, and total revenue helps firms to make these decisions because the profit that a firm can earn depends on the total revenue and the total cost.
339:
rise due to an increase in quantity if the percentage increase in quantity is larger than the percentage decrease in price. The percentage change in the price and quantity determine whether the demand for a product is
106:, which is the price of the goods multiplied by the quantity of the sold goods. A monopolist's total revenue can be graphed as in Figure 1, in which Price (P) is the height of the box, and Quantity (Q) is the width. 201:) is the inverse demand function (the demand function solved out for price in terms of quantity demanded). Continuing to use Figure 1 as an example, price can be written as a function of quantity: 187: 286: 475: 353:
Price and total revenue have a negative relationship when demand is elastic (price elasticity > 1), which means that increases in price will lead to decreases in total revenue.
350:
Price and total revenue have a positive relationship when demand is inelastic (price elasticity < 1), which means that when price increases, total revenue will increase too.
356:
Price changes will not affect total revenue when the demand is unit elastic (price elasticity = 1). Maximum total revenue is achieved where the elasticity of demand is 1.
130: 104: 234: 364:
When demand is inelastic, an increase in supply will lead to a decrease in total revenue while a decrease in supply will lead to an increase in total revenue.
367:
When demand is elastic, an increase in supply will lead to an increase in total revenue while a decrease in supply will lead to a decrease in total revenue.
458: 135: 80:’s total revenue is the total receipts it can obtain from selling goods or services to buyers. It can be written as 346:
The changes in total revenue are based on the price elasticity of demand, and there are general rules for them:
380:
Total revenue can help with a firm's operational decision: whether the firm should be shut down or kept open.
239: 19:
is the total receipts a seller can obtain from selling goods or services to buyers. It can be written as
340: 109: 83: 36: 132:, (i.e., total revenue) equals the area of the box. Letting TR be the total revenue function: 204: 8: 430: 32: 454: 387:, if the total revenue (TR) that a firm can earn from operating will not exceed the 498: 425: 453:. USA: Cengage Learning. pp. 94–98, 106–107, 260–262, 283–288 & 304–308. 69:
Figure 1. A linear demand curve (top) and resulting total revenue curve (bottom)
23:, which is the price of the goods multiplied by the quantity of the sold goods. 52: 375: 492: 388: 320: 360:
The above movements along the demand curve result from changes in supply:
308: 77: 384: 333: 296: 400: 63: 376:
Relationship between total revenue and operational decision
248: 144: 236:, and be substituted into TR(Q) to get the TR function 476:"Total revenue and elasticity (video) | Khan Academy" 242: 207: 138: 112: 86: 280: 228: 181: 124: 98: 391:(VC) of operation, the firm should be shut down. 334:Relationship between total revenue and elasticity 490: 411:The rules are opposite for entering a market: 182:{\displaystyle {\mathit {TR}}(Q)=P(Q)\times Q} 35:firm faces a demand curve that is infinitely 281:{\displaystyle {\mathit {TR}}=-Q^{2}+6Q} 491: 448: 26: 193:is the quantity of output sold, and 13: 245: 141: 14: 510: 473: 451:Principles of Microeconomics, 7e 415:If TR > TC, enter the market. 319: 307: 295: 76:As with a perfect competitor, a 62: 51: 407:If TR < TC, exit the market. 467: 442: 170: 164: 155: 149: 1: 436: 7: 449:Mankiw, N. Gregory (2013). 419: 42: 10: 515: 395:If TR < VC, shut down. 125:{\displaystyle P\times Q} 99:{\displaystyle P\times Q} 282: 230: 229:{\displaystyle P=-Q+6} 183: 126: 100: 283: 231: 184: 127: 101: 33:perfectly competitive 341:elastic or inelastic 240: 205: 136: 110: 84: 431:Profit maximization 278: 226: 179: 122: 96: 27:Perfect competitor 460:978-1-285-16590-5 506: 484: 483: 471: 465: 464: 446: 426:Marginal revenue 323: 311: 299: 287: 285: 284: 279: 268: 267: 252: 251: 235: 233: 232: 227: 188: 186: 185: 180: 148: 147: 131: 129: 128: 123: 105: 103: 102: 97: 66: 55: 514: 513: 509: 508: 507: 505: 504: 503: 489: 488: 487: 472: 468: 461: 447: 443: 439: 422: 378: 336: 331: 330: 329: 328: 327: 324: 316: 315: 312: 304: 303: 300: 263: 259: 244: 243: 241: 238: 237: 206: 203: 202: 140: 139: 137: 134: 133: 111: 108: 107: 85: 82: 81: 74: 73: 72: 71: 70: 67: 58: 57: 56: 45: 29: 12: 11: 5: 512: 502: 501: 486: 485: 466: 459: 440: 438: 435: 434: 433: 428: 421: 418: 417: 416: 409: 408: 397: 396: 389:variable costs 377: 374: 369: 368: 365: 358: 357: 354: 351: 335: 332: 325: 318: 317: 313: 306: 305: 301: 294: 293: 292: 291: 290: 277: 274: 271: 266: 262: 258: 255: 250: 247: 225: 222: 219: 216: 213: 210: 178: 175: 172: 169: 166: 163: 160: 157: 154: 151: 146: 143: 121: 118: 115: 95: 92: 89: 68: 61: 60: 59: 50: 49: 48: 47: 46: 44: 41: 28: 25: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 511: 500: 497: 496: 494: 481: 477: 470: 462: 456: 452: 445: 441: 432: 429: 427: 424: 423: 414: 413: 412: 406: 405: 404: 402: 394: 393: 392: 390: 386: 381: 373: 366: 363: 362: 361: 355: 352: 349: 348: 347: 344: 342: 322: 310: 298: 289: 275: 272: 269: 264: 260: 256: 253: 223: 220: 217: 214: 211: 208: 200: 196: 192: 176: 173: 167: 161: 158: 152: 119: 116: 113: 93: 90: 87: 79: 65: 54: 40: 38: 34: 24: 22: 18: 17:Total revenue 480:Khan Academy 479: 469: 450: 444: 410: 398: 382: 379: 370: 359: 345: 337: 198: 194: 190: 75: 30: 20: 16: 15: 474:Khan, Sal. 437:References 78:monopolist 385:short run 257:− 215:− 174:× 117:× 91:× 493:Category 420:See also 401:long run 326:Figure 4 314:Figure 3 302:Figure 2 189:, where 43:Monopoly 499:Revenue 399:In the 383:In the 37:elastic 457:  21:P × Q 455:ISBN 495:: 478:. 343:. 31:A 482:. 463:. 276:Q 273:6 270:+ 265:2 261:Q 254:= 249:R 246:T 224:6 221:+ 218:Q 212:= 209:P 199:Q 197:( 195:P 191:Q 177:Q 171:) 168:Q 165:( 162:P 159:= 156:) 153:Q 150:( 145:R 142:T 120:Q 114:P 94:Q 88:P

Index

perfectly competitive
elastic


monopolist



elastic or inelastic
short run
variable costs
long run
Marginal revenue
Profit maximization
ISBN
978-1-285-16590-5
"Total revenue and elasticity (video) | Khan Academy"
Category
Revenue

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.