Knowledge

Issues affecting the single transferable vote

Source đź“ť

587:(with the exception where above-the-line voting systems are in place); this in turn can create some difficulty when attempting to analyse how an STV election's results compare with the nationwide partisan makeup. One common method of estimating the party identification of voters is to assume their top-preference on their ballot represents a candidate from their preferred party, however this method of estimation is made more complicated by the possibility of independent candidates and of cross-party voting. However valid comparisons have and can still be made if sufficient data and information are available. In Victoria, Australia, it is possible to make a direct comparison between the Australian Senate election and the Victorian Upper House elections although individual circumstance will always exist. Voting patterns have shown that most voters stay with their chosen party within a limited percentage range based on local issues and circumstances. The main advantage in Victoria's case is that both systems are similar in design with one being a subset of the other. Victoria held its first multi-member proportional representation election in November 2006 for the 283:, voters in STV are not explicitly constrained by parties even when they do exist; voters may ignore candidate party labels and mix their preferred candidate rankings between parties. Similarly, candidates may achieve electoral success by obtaining a quota of voters not generally within their own party, perhaps by winning transfers from moderates or by championing a specific issue contrary to party doctrine. STV advocates argue that, by requiring a candidate to appeal to the supporters of other candidates for their second and further preferences, it reduces adversarial confrontation, and indeed, gives a substantial advantage to candidates that broaden their appeal by being not only collegial but as open-minded and flexible in their principles as they can manage. STV detractors see that as a flaw, arguing that political parties should be able to structure public debate, mobilize and engage the electorate, and develop policy alternatives. 636:, successive governments lowered this. A parliamentary committee in 2010 discussed the "increasing trend towards the creation of three-seat constituencies in Ireland." They found "a larger district magnitude is shown to have positive effects in relation to the representation of women and minorities, as well as allowing for a plurality of ideas in terms of policy." They recommended not less than four-seaters, except where the geographic size of such a constituency would be disproportionately large. (although the large number of representatives in Irish legislative chambers and the small size of the island even as a whole makes the term "large" a relative thing.) 401:. Consequently, voters sometimes, for example, rank only the candidates of a single party, or of their most preferred parties. A minority of voters, especially if they do not fully understand the system, might even "bullet vote", only expressing a first preference. Allowing voters to rank only as many candidates as they wish grants them greater freedom, but can also lead to some voters ranking so few candidates that their vote eventually becomes "exhausted"; that happens if at a certain point during the count it needs to be transferred but cannot be transferred. It thereby loses an opportunity to influence the result. (In 494:
party, but have no strong preference between them, the voter is likely to number them downwards from the top of the ballot sheet, in normal reading fashion. Later preferences to candidates of another party are likely to be numbered in the same way. If candidates' names are listed alphabetically, this pattern will mean that earlier preferences will go to candidates earlier in the alphabet. Over a series of elections, such a minor bias would have a cumulative effect, as elected members stand for election again. In Ireland, it has been suggested that names on ballot papers should be printed in random order to prevent this.
546:, all original states have the same number of senators regardless of population, intended to guard the interests of smaller states like Tasmania and South Australia against larger states like New South Wales and Victoria (both states containing a majority of Australia's population). However, results are proportional within a state; and if preferences are similar across large and small states no major disproportionality is generated. Each of Australia's states are strongly urbanised to a similar (~75% or more), and so rural-urban political divides are similar in each state, resulting in a fairly proportional composition 334:
candidates; however, if voters vote for all candidates from a particular party before any other candidates and before stopping expressing preferences, then too many candidates is not an issue. In Malta, where voters tend to stick tightly to party preferences, parties frequently stand more candidates than there are seats to be elected. Similarly, in Australian Senate elections, voters also tend to vote along party lines due to the relative ease of endorsing a party's declared preference order, even though the parties do not encourage voters to peruse that order, but urge them to take it on trust, as evidenced by their
325:, candidates have a significant incentive to convince voters to rank them explicitly first as their top preference, rather than merely higher. This incentive to attain top preferences, in turn, may lead to a strategy of candidates placing greater importance on a core group of supporters. Avoiding early elimination, however, is usually not enough to win election, as a candidate must still subsequently win enough votes on transfers to meet the quota; consequently, strategies that sacrifice wide secondary support in favor of primary support amidst a core group may ultimately fail unless the group is particularly large. 576:
the voters' assessment of their preferences for the candidates is most importantly based on the voters' expectations of how the candidate would act and vote if elected, and that might be influenced by the character, ethnicity, age, place of residence or gender as examples. A perceived problem arises from the fact that voters and the political elite are often not in accord with what sort of proportionality should be achieved. Increased voter choice and control reduces the power and influence of the political elite to determine the political debate.
378: 460:. For above the line, voters are instructed to number at least their first six preferences; however, a "savings provision" is in place to ensure that ballots will still be counted if less than six are given. For below the line, voters are required to number at least their first 12 preferences. Voters are free to continue numbering as many preferences as they like beyond the minimum number specified. Another savings provision allows ballot papers with at least 6 below the line preferences to be formal. 905:, STV-B, affects some issues of STV. Borda counts include deeper preferences, and so contain more information than is held in current first place votes. Borda counts would capture the popularity of that Condorcet winner described in the preceding paragraph, preventing immediate elimination. Elimination by Borda counts creates other features for STV including promotion of moderate candidates and increased stability in the face of small changes of preferences. 512:
as a district or constituency system, an election using STV may not guarantee proportionality across all districts put together. Differential turnout across districts, for example, may alter the impact of individual votes in different constituencies, and when combined with rounding errors associated with a finite number of winners in each constituency the election as a whole may throw up anomalous results from a purely party perspective.
694:
even smaller districts municipally, to a single three-seater district of all 1,737,000 people for election to the European Parliament. In State of Victoria (Australia) 40 members are elected for the Legislative Council, five per district through STV, with 3.1M votes cast in 2006. With 360,000 to 375,000 votes cast in each district. Previous to PR being adopted, the Legislative Council held 44 members, with half elected each two years.
210: 33: 489:(lower house of parliament) elected in 2002, about 4.5% of members had surnames beginning with A, 8% beginning with B, and 12% beginning with C. From listings in the Eircom telephone directories for the 01, 06 and 07/09 areas combined, the expected percentages would be about 1.5%, 7% and 9.5% respectively. Similar deviations from the norm have been noted after previous elections. The effect seems to be minimal, as the 535:; STV alone would also have given the second most popular party a parliamentary majority in the 1987, 1996 and 2008 Maltese elections. This kind of difference due to rounding error can occur with any PR system used at a district level, although greater rounding error occurs with smaller districts and there is a tendency for STV elections to use smaller districts when compared with PR elections employing party lists. 135: 583:- an example STV election using the Droop quota method for 9 seats and with no exhausted preferences would guarantee representation to every distinct group of 10% of the voters, with at most just under 10% of the vote being wasted as unneeded excess. Unlike other proportional representation methods employing party lists, voters in STV do not explicitly state their preferred 406:
First Past The Post. Back-up preferences are not consulted if the vote is cast at the start for a candidate who wins in the end as the last seat is filled, or cast for a candidate who is eliminated at the end. They are also not used if they are marked for a candidate who has already been elected or eliminated.)
321:, as reducing a particular opponent's ranking among voters does not necessarily elevate one's own; if negative campaigning is seen as distasteful by the voters, the practice may even prove harmful to the attacking candidate. Conversely, in order to avoid elimination in early counting rounds by having too few 575:
PR-STV differs from other PR systems in that it allows the voter to decide the issues that should matter for them. In most PR systems, the voter can only influence a single aspect - party representation. STV allows the voter to choose other criteria that can be used to create the proportionality:
843:
is more pronounced and predictable. Non-monotonicity, in turn, makes it possible under some circumstances to elect a preferred candidate by reducing their position on some of the ballots; by helping elect a candidate who displaces the preferred candidate's main rival, a voter may cause the preferred
758:
Under WIGT, the 50 E > A > C > D votes again "skip" candidate A and transfer to C who wins the second seat. All C's votes (both the E > A > C > D votes and the C > B votes) then transfer at reduced value. As a
754:
The quota is 100 and A is elected at stage 1. E is the first candidate to be eliminated. Under SGT, the 50 E > A > C > D votes "skip" candidate A and transfer to candidate C; who is then elected. These votes then transfer again to candidate D who wins the final
714:
One potential strategy in STV involves casting a first preference vote for a candidate that has no chance of winning. This vote will then be transferred at full value and carry more weight in determining the winners at the later stages of the count. This strategy can be effective due to two features
693:
A related question is the number of people (voters) in the district, and the possibility of an effective democratic campaign by a candidate in a large district where campaign costs are high. In Northern Ireland, districts range from 96,000 people in six-seaters for the Northern Ireland Assembly, and
628:
A larger number of candidates elected also results in a smaller number of wasted votes on the final count. However, larger districts and the implicit larger number of candidates also increase the difficulty of giving meaningful rankings to all candidates from the perspective of the individual voter,
605:
Because STV is proportional, larger districts reduce the support a candidate knows will be enough to become elected as a percentage of the district vote. The usual choice is the Droop quota. With 9 to be elected, for example, any who reach (with or without transfers) 10% electoral support will win a
405:
elections, many, sometimes most, votes are disregarded, as there is no opportunity to mark back-up preferences. To the extent that voters mark back-up preferences and the back-up preferences consulted - many are not consulted even if marked - the portion of votes ignored under STV is less than under
328:
There are also tactical considerations for political parties in the number of candidates they stand in an election where full ballots are not required. Standing too few candidates may result in all of them being elected in the early stages, and votes being transferred to candidates of other parties.
511:
The outcome of voting under PR-STV is proportional in party terms within a single election to the collective preference of voters, assuming voters have ranked their real preferences and vote along strict party lines. However, due to other voting mechanisms usually used in conjunction with STV, such
1177:
ince the 1980 general election all members of the House of Representatives for ACT electorates have usually been members of the Australian Labor Party. Throughout much of this period, one senator has been a member of the ALP, the other senator from the Liberal Party. Oneparty representation in the
765:
Under SGT, the E > A > C > D voters effectively determine the winners of the two final seats. Under WIGT, as a result of the E > A > C > D votes failing to contribute to the election of candidate A and transferring at an
667:
There is no theoretical upper limit to the size of districts in STV, and they may not even be needed at all: Thomas Hare's original proposal was for a single, nationwide district. In theory, STV ensures the election of particularly small minorities provided they secure a quota's worth of votes, if
473:
begin with an early letter in the alphabet enjoy a small electoral advantage over candidates with later letters. To solve this problem some systems involve a random ordering of candidates, or an ordering that changes from one ballot paper to another (the latter is often called the Robson rotation,
351:
Electoral stasis is a condition that can arise when an electorate cannot realistically change its political composition, regardless of the swing occurring in a general election. A safe seat in a single member electoral system is one that is in electoral stasis. Proportional representation systems,
922:
Another option is to have a head official or remaining members of the elected body appoint a new member to fulfill the vacancy. In Australia, for example, the state legislatures appoint replacements members to the Australian Senate, now done at the suggestion of the party of the outgoing senator.
872:
Some modifications to STV have been proposed in order to pass monotonicity and other criteria. The most common method of proposed modification to STV is to alter the order in which candidates are eliminated: theoretically, a candidate who ranked second on every ballot could be the first candidate
769:
While this appears an effective strategy in theory there are a number of problems with it in practice. Firstly accurate information is needed about how other voters are going to vote, in practice this information is difficult to obtain. Secondly if all voters vote for candidates they believe will
493:
median surname currently falls within the letter K, which accurately reflects the distribution of Irish names. An analysis of likely voting patterns seems to predict a small bias of this kind. A voter votes 1 for the candidate they most favour. If they wish to support other candidates of the same
439:
from 1984 until 2013 a voter could either rank the candidates individually "below the line" or place the number 1 in a box "above the line" to vote for a predetermined ordering of candidates drawn up by one of the political parties. This system diminished the emphasis on individual candidates and
972:
unless there is more than one vacancy); this allows each party to choose a new candidate and all voters to participate. This often leads to a different party winning the seat (usually one of the largest parties, since the quota is large). In the Republic of Ireland, by-elections are used for the
468:
The simplest way to list candidates on a ballot paper is alphabetically, though they may also be grouped by party. However, any fixed ordering will give some candidates an unfair advantage, because some voters, consciously or otherwise, are influenced in their ordering of candidates by the order
868:
is not. Intuitively, a candidate who was elected largely because of transfers from two similar groups (neither obtaining a quota) may not be elected when the number of winning candidates increases, as both groups would instead get their preferred candidates elected (with the new, smaller quota)
368:
The smaller the number of members to be elected to a division, the more likely that the electorate (and division) will be in electoral stasis. The larger the number of members returned by an electorate the greater the chance that a voter that changes their vote can influence the outcome of the
195:
However, as with all voting systems, once PR-STV is understood there remain a number of areas of controversy surrounding its use. In particular, arguments for and against proportional representation in general are frequently referenced in debates among electorates considering STV, however the
333:
being spread too thinly amongst them, and consequently several potential winners with broad second-preference appeal may be eliminated before others are elected and their second-preference votes distributed. This effect is amplified when voters do not stick tightly to their preferred party's
502:
in the 1937 Senate election in New South Wales resulted in legislation in 1940 that changed the order of candidates names from an alphabetical ranking to a grouping in party columns on a horizontal ballot paper where the order of candidates' names within each party column were allowed to be
413:, some PR-STV systems oblige voters to give a complete ordering of all of the candidates in an election (if a voter does not rank all candidates their ballot may be considered spoilt outright or not until the lack of a marked preference affects the count, a loophole used by those who cast a 424:" in which a voter that has no strong opinions about their preferences simply ranks them in the given order. Some jurisdictions compromise by setting a minimum number of preferences that must be filled for a ballot paper to be valid (semi-optional preferential voting). (For example, 913:
When compared with other voting methods, the question of how to fill vacancies which occur under STV can be difficult given the way that results depend upon transfers from multiple candidates. As well by-elections to fill a single seat in a multi-member district can be expensive.
710:
voting systems that choose a single winner. A number of methods of tactical or strategic voting exist that can be used in elections conducted using STV. In general these methods are only effective in marginal districts and only affect the allocation of a single seat per district.
791:
constituency. There were 12 candidates and almost 44,000 votes cast. The most common pattern (for the three candidates from one party in a particular order) was chosen by only 800 voters, and more than 16,000 patterns were chosen by just one voter each. The number of possible
343:(parliamentary) constituencies. Transfers are often not along party lines, but rather go towards more prominent local personalities. Election posters for the most prominent candidate of a political party usually list preferred 2nd (and possibly 3rd) preferences for that party. 981:
where voters in the Dáil constituency or Seanad panel vote to fill the vacancy or vacancies. This removes the balance of proportionality of the original election. The costs of holding a by-election in a multi-member constituency is considerable. In a recent review of the
301:
Some practices overlaid on PR-STV, however, may encourage the role of political parties and actually strengthen them. In Australian Senate elections, where a combination of large districts (statewide elections), mandatory complete ballots (preferencing all candidates), and
653:; because gerrymandering is splitting of voters into separate contests, fewer and larger multi-member districts, which are integral part of STV, mitigate this. As well, if all are represented proportionally in each district, shifting of boundaries makes little difference. 364:
have always returned one member from each of the two major parties. In an electorate returning three members, electoral stasis occurs when the weaker party is able to gain a quota (25.01%). The more popular party will then win two seats and the weaker party one seat.
612:
An STV election for a district with only two seats will result in a largely unchanging result of each seat going to the most popular and second most popular party so long as neither party falls below a quota of 33.3% of the vote - similar results to the (non STV)
455:
As a result of the changes, voters may assign their preferences for parties above the line (numbering as many boxes as they wish), or individual candidates below the line, and are not required to fill all of the boxes. Both above and below the line voting now use
196:
specific implications of a particular STV system can be examined as well. Most of the arguments for and against STV and proportional representation in general are based around the expected outcomes of the alternative proposed system and not on the system itself.
338:
distributed outside polling booths, rather than individually casting their own complete preference order. In the Republic of Ireland, the main political parties usually give careful consideration as to how many candidates to put forward in various
1512: 355:
In an electorate returning two members simultaneously, the quota for successful candidacy, 33.34%, is easy for both parties in a two-party-dominated assembly to reach if their core demographic voter base exceeds the quota. For example, the
497:
In New Zealand's local body elections, each ballot paper is randomly ordered but alphabetic effects are still observed, probably due to the provision of an accompanying booklet that lists the candidates alphabetically. In Australia, the
629:
and may result in increased numbers of exhausted ballots and reliance on party labels or group voting tickets. (although not all STV systems require votes to rank all candidates but only ask them to rank as many as the voter wants to.)
931:
to provide that the legislature must elect a member of the same party as the outgoing senator. Vacancies in the New South Wales Legislative Council are filled similarly, by a joint sitting of both the legislative council and assembly.
656:
It is noticed that gerrymandering relies on wasted votes to award the "last seat" in each district, so proportional representation systems such as STV with larger multi-member districts are intrinsically more difficult to gerrymander.
782:
patterns will be unique to individual voters, which could allow voters to identify themselves in a context of corruption or intimidation, with transparency of vote counting undermining the secrecy of ballots. For example, in the
860:: a candidate elected in an n seat constituency may or may not be elected in the same constituency with n + 1 seats even when voters express exactly the same preferences. This is due to the use of quotas; list PR by a 848:
which can result in a more favorable outcome to an STV voter by not voting at all. However, a voter who truncates a candidate off the ballot does not harm a ranked candidate, nor is another truncated candidate helped
557:, Australia, legislation ensures that each Legislative Council region contains almost the same number of constituents and elects the same number of legislators in each, also resulting in closely proportional results. 1493: 389:. STV systems in use in different countries vary both as to ballot design and to whether or not voters are obliged to provide a full list of preferences (full preferential voting). In jurisdictions such as the 274:
by the voters, and candidates of one party can be elected on transfers from voters for other parties. Hence, the use of STV may reduce the role of political parties in the electoral process and correspondingly
885:
to rank candidates for elimination order. Some of these modifications alter STV in a way such that it no longer reduces to instant-runoff voting when applied to a single seat but instead reduces to some other
1332:
Let us have a look at the situation in Cork city when they fought a local election as one constituency with everybody up in a free-for all. ... We had 72 names on the ballot paper, out of which 21 were to be
1509: 800:
of the number of candidates, so almost half a billion possibilities if there are 12 candidates; but if voters can stop expressing preferences then over 1.3 billion possibilities with 12 candidates.
564:
is intentionally malapportioned to give half the seats to non-Perth (largely and remote) areas despite having only 35% of the WA population. This has benefited rural focussed parties like the
660:
Larger districts can also make for significantly harder tactical voting: since the problem of making correct assumptions about other voter's behavior and rearranging one's tactical ballot is
553:
avoids the use of districts entirely, electing all 21 members using a single, statewide constituency and guaranteeing results that are proportional to the final allocation of preferences. In
877:. Meek noted this problem in proposing their variation of transferring votes to nearly eliminate tactical voting in STV, however Meek himself did not propose a method for satisfying the 192:
single transferable vote in 2005, according to polls most of the "no" voters gave their reason as "wasn't knowledgeable" when they were asked why, specifically, they voted against STV.
542:
across districts can also cause disproportionate results for the legislature as a whole, but they are far less disproportionate than non-PR systems. In the PR-STV elections to the
1474: 579:
PR-STV provides proportionality by transferring votes to minimise waste of votes, and therefore also minimises the number of unrepresented voters. In this way PR-STV provides
231: 50: 420:
However, when there is a large number of candidates the work put on the voter by the full preferential voting rule may prove burdensome and can lead to random voting, or "
352:
such as STV ballots, can also be in electoral stasis. These “safe seats” can be ignored by political party strategists, who will allocate resources to other electorates.
1490: 646:, after which the two large parties shrank the district magnitude to five and called an early election, which cut the Green representation from four seats down to one. 770:
lose, these candidates will win. In general, this strategy will not work if everyone uses it. Little evidence exists of the use of this strategy in the real world.
469:
found on the ballot paper. For example, studies conducted in the Republic of Ireland, where candidates are listed alphabetically, have shown that candidates whose
317:
strategy in PR-STV elections may differ significantly from other voting systems. In particular, individual candidates in STV have little incentive for negative
1057: 440:
increases the power of party leaders that submit the predetermined rankings; in practice it may even lead to a system resembling, but not being identical to
1178:
House has also been common for the Northern Territory, so that its two senators are also essential to providing that territory with balanced representation.
97: 17: 531:, leading to an amendment adjusting the voting system to allow for the possibility of bonus seats and making the Maltese voting system more similar to an 69: 1409: 939:
of a candidate nominated by the departed councillor's party colleagues, although in Northern Ireland this requires unanimous approval from the council.
76: 286:
Unlike List PR, PR-STV can be used in elections in organizations without any political parties at all, such as in municipal non-partisan elections,
1096:
Senate voting changes explained in Australian Electoral Commission advertisements By political reporter Stephanie Anderson. Posted Tue at 12:00am
83: 1315: 1427: 65: 1421:
Chris Geller (2005) Single Transferable Vote with Borda Elimination: Proportional Representation, Moderation, Quasi-Chaos, and Stability
1471: 1121:"Booklet position effects, and two new statistics to gauge voter understanding of the need to rank candidates in preferential elections" 766:
increased value, C wins a seat as opposed to D. SGT systems are more vulnerable to this form of tactical voting than WIGT systems.
1458: 1275: 1222: 1006:
member is replaced with the top eligible name from a replacement list submitted by the candidate at the time of the original election.
690:
elections, held from 1991 to the present. Held state-wide, it elected 21 members in one single contest - 4.7M votes were cast in 2019.
625:; where the territory's two senators have been divided by the two major parties, bipartisan but uncompetitive representation by design 444:. However it was still possible for independent candidates to be elected as has been shown in the 2007 Federal Senate elections where 1397: 1162: 1095: 602:
in terms of the number of candidates elected (district magnitude) and, to a lesser extent, the total size of the body being elected.
1191: 778:
If there are a large number of candidates, which is quite common in single transferable vote elections, then it is likely that many
924: 310:, political parties gain significant power in determining election results by adjusting the relative ordering of their candidates. 828: 720: 994:
Another alternative is to have the candidates themselves create an ordered list of successors before leaving their seat. In the
561: 441: 1238: 90: 723:
and Newland-Britton Northern Ireland consider for transfer only the last parcel of votes received by an elected candidate.
687: 550: 1385: 788: 1535: 703: 257: 116: 986:, in Australia, the cost of holding a by-election for a single casual vacancy was estimated to surpass $ 1 million. 435:
rather than having to identify manually a complete list of individual preferences. For example, in elections to the
239: 824: 180:
A frequent concern with PR-STV among electorates considering its adoption is its relative complexity compared with
1068: 639:
When Northern Ireland adopted STV, they found five-seaters not sufficiently proportional and chose six-seaters.
235: 54: 448:
was elected. In 2016 group tickets were abolished to avoid undue influence of preference deals and a form of
643: 588: 554: 153: 734:
For example, in an election in which 5 candidates are contesting 3 seats the following 400 votes are cast:
457: 449: 398: 784: 633: 479: 270:
STV differs from all other proportional representation systems in actual use in that representatives are
726:
Both simple Gregorian transfer systems and weighted inclusive Gregorian transfer (WIGT) systems such as
680: 609:
Some STV elections make use of districts with the number of seats available as small as two or three.
1084: 928: 524: 172:
proportional representation that form the basis of discussions between its advocates and detractors.
1085:
Senate Results: South Australia - Federal Election 2007 - ABC (Australian Broadcasting Corporation)
861: 539: 475: 220: 169: 148: 1434: 865: 845: 820: 527:
winning 51% of the first-preference vote. Controversy over the election ultimately resulted in a
224: 181: 43: 431:
To facilitate a complete ballot, some PR-STV systems provide the voter with the option of using
832: 516: 357: 330: 322: 935:
In the Republic of Ireland and Northern Ireland, vacancies on local authorities are filled by
869:
rather than automatically compromising on their mutual second choice as their votes transfer.
969: 528: 386: 1198: 887: 836: 676: 318: 307: 276: 759:
result of this transfer candidate B wins the third seat. The WIGT winners are A, C and B.
632:
While Ireland originally had a median district magnitude of five (range three to nine) in
8: 999: 995: 895: 878: 835:. Failure to satisfy independence of irrelevant alternatives makes STV slightly prone to 664:, the difficulty of tactical voting increases sharply as the number of candidates grows. 432: 402: 390: 291: 1350: 1020: 622: 520: 314: 1345: 1120: 306:
has resulted - since they were introduced in 1983 - in the near 95% usage of partisan
168:
There are a number of complications and issues surrounding the application and use of
1452: 1290: 1269: 1216: 1044: 983: 779: 618: 569: 543: 490: 486: 436: 361: 340: 303: 143: 978: 844:
candidate to profit from transfers resulting from the rival's defeat. STV fails the
823:
that they pass. No preference voting system satisfies all the criteria described in
1373: 1003: 959: 882: 874: 672: 410: 394: 377: 185: 671:
The 1925 Irish Senate election used one district to elect nineteen places and the
503:
predetermined by the party. That aspect of the Senate ballot paper still applies.
279:
in the resulting government. Unlike proportional representation systems employing
1516: 1497: 1478: 1251: 857: 809: 614: 584: 271: 1149:"Elections in Malta: The Single-Transferable-Vote System in Action, 1921 - 2004" 840: 650: 598:
Another issue commonly considered with STV elections is the size of the voting
686:
Perhaps the STV governmental election electing the most members ever were the
1529: 707: 642:
Tasmania had seven-seaters until the Green Party won the balance of power in
445: 421: 414: 881:. Other theorists have proposed further refinements of STV, such as using a 1302: 894:
is one example of multiple winner ranked voting method which satisfies the
762:
The Meek system, which is immune to this strategy, elects A, B and D.
565: 1045:
Video postmortem on BC-STV referendum (British Columbia's version of STV).
499: 1107: 1025: 965: 902: 819:
Academic analysis of voting systems such as STV generally centers on the
793: 287: 649:
Larger electoral districts can also significantly reduce the effects of
335: 280: 606:
seat, whereas with 5 to be elected 16.7% is enough to ensure success.
1346:"S.I. No. 249/1965 - Cork County Borough Electoral Areas Order, 1965" 1189:
Constituency Commission Report on Dáil Constituencies, 2004, p. 68. "
948: 936: 797: 532: 1246: 964:
A third alternative to fulfill a vacancy is to hold a single-winner
923:
Before this rule, disputes over Senate vacancies contributed to the
209: 32: 599: 425: 1015: 891: 661: 470: 974: 1316:"Committee on Finance. - Electoral Bill, 1962: Committee Stage" 727: 295: 189: 385:
As seen above, voters in an STV election rank candidates on a
199: 1236:
Joint Committee on the Constitution, Fourth Report, p. 177. "
1148: 1163:"Representation of Commonwealth Territories in the Senate" 750:
50: E > A > C > D
831:(like most other vote-based ordering systems) as well as 901:
Eliminating losing candidates in reverse order of their
538:
Similarly to differences in voter turnout, instances of
839:, albeit less so than with plurality methods where the 1412:
complete table of votes cast Dublin North (zip file)
730:
do not transfer votes to already elected candidates.
184:
methods. For example, when the Canadian province of
706:tactical voting is possible in all non-dictatorial 428:requires voter to mark at least five preferences.) 57:. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. 1510:Replacement Candidates for the European Parliament 927:, ultimately resulting in a 1977 amendment to the 1527: 719:Simple Gregorian transfer (SGT) systems such as 66:"Issues affecting the single transferable vote" 787:, the electronic votes were published for the 399:rank as many or as few candidates as they wish 1465: 381:Senate ballot paper used in Victoria for 2016 329:Standing too many candidates might result in 1183: 1038: 755:seat. The SGT winners are A, C and D. 238:. Unsourced material may be challenged and 200:Effects on parties, factions and candidates 142:It has been suggested that this article be 1472:Membership of local authorities in Ireland 1065:Largest Remainder (newsletter of PRSA NSW) 803: 1503: 1484: 1100: 814: 258:Learn how and when to remove this message 117:Learn how and when to remove this message 1141: 925:Australian constitutional crisis of 1975 738:105: A > D > B 523:winning a majority of seats despite the 376: 1366: 1055: 829:independence of irrelevant alternatives 617:in Chile. This can also be observed in 14: 1528: 1457:: CS1 maint: archived copy as title ( 1313: 1274:: CS1 maint: archived copy as title ( 1221:: CS1 maint: archived copy as title ( 1118: 1108:http://www.oireachtas.ie/members-hist/ 827:: in particular, STV fails to achieve 773: 568:compared to other parties such as the 562:Western Australian Legislative Council 463: 442:party-list proportional representation 1415: 1398:Irish Commission on Electronic Voting 1283: 1230: 1112: 236:adding citations to reliable sources 203: 128: 55:adding citations to reliable sources 26: 18:Countback (single transferable vote) 989: 688:New South Wales Legislative Council 551:New South Wales Legislative Council 346: 24: 1322:. pp. Vol.201 No.4 p.48 c.604 1303:The Irish Senate elections of 1925 1160: 1089: 697: 506: 188:held a referendum on adopting the 25: 1547: 679:until subdivided in time for the 864:is similarly affected, though a 668:very large districts were used. 593: 372: 208: 133: 31: 1410:Dublin County Returning Officer 1403: 1391: 1379: 1338: 1307: 1296: 1056:Lesslie, Stephen (2008-06-10), 856:STV is also susceptible to the 482:who championed such a system). 42:needs additional citations for 1314:Blaney, Neil (27 March 1963). 1154: 1078: 1067:, pp. 2–5, archived from 1049: 953: 917: 890:, such as a Condorcet method. 873:eliminated even if they are a 715:of some STV counting systems. 13: 1: 1031: 825:Arrow's impossibility theorem 704:Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem 175: 942: 908: 458:optional preferential voting 450:optional preferential voting 7: 1009: 785:2002 Irish general election 10: 1552: 957: 946: 807: 1491:Seanad Panel By-Elections 1293:". Accessed Aug 12, 2005. 929:Constitution of Australia 1536:Single transferable vote 1372:Markus Schulze (2004). " 1291:A note on Gerrymandering 1151:. Accessed Aug 11, 2005. 862:largest remainder method 747:75: D > B 744:80: C > B 397:voters are permitted to 170:single transferable vote 159:Proposed since May 2024. 149:Single transferable vote 866:highest averages method 846:participation criterion 804:Vote management systems 621:representation for the 1119:Ombler, Franz (2006). 821:voting system criteria 815:Voting system criteria 675:used a single 21-seat 517:1981 election in Malta 382: 331:first-preference votes 323:first preference votes 1500:Accessed 14 Oct, 2005 581:Droop proportionality 529:constitutional crisis 380: 1519:Accessed 7 Oct, 2005 1481:Accessed 7 Oct, 2005 1320:Dáil Éireann debates 888:single winner system 837:strategic nomination 796:with no ties is the 677:local electoral area 433:group voting tickets 319:campaign advertising 308:group voting tickets 232:improve this section 51:improve this article 1000:Republic of Ireland 996:European Parliament 896:Condorcet criterion 879:Condorcet criterion 774:Uniqueness of votes 681:1967 local election 589:Legislative Council 533:open-list PR system 464:Alphabetic ordering 403:First Past the Post 391:Republic of Ireland 387:preferential ballot 1515:2006-01-13 at the 1496:2006-01-13 at the 1477:2006-10-01 at the 1354:. 13 December 1965 1351:Irish Statute Book 1289:Whyte, Nicholas. " 1058:"Electoral stasis" 1021:Quota Borda system 623:Northern Territory 383: 1423:Electoral Studies 1386:Election database 1161:Sloane, Michael. 984:City of Melbourne 794:complete rankings 780:preference voting 702:According to the 619:Australian Senate 549:By contrast, the 544:Australian Senate 525:Nationalist Party 515:For example, the 437:Australian Senate 411:exhausted ballots 362:Australian Senate 336:how-to-vote cards 304:compulsory voting 268: 267: 260: 166: 165: 161: 127: 126: 119: 101: 16:(Redirected from 1543: 1520: 1507: 1501: 1488: 1482: 1469: 1463: 1462: 1456: 1448: 1446: 1445: 1439: 1433:. Archived from 1432: 1419: 1413: 1407: 1401: 1395: 1389: 1388:February 1, 2004 1383: 1377: 1370: 1364: 1363: 1361: 1359: 1342: 1336: 1335: 1329: 1327: 1311: 1305: 1300: 1294: 1287: 1281: 1279: 1273: 1265: 1263: 1262: 1256: 1250:. Archived from 1243: 1234: 1228: 1226: 1220: 1212: 1210: 1209: 1203: 1197:. Archived from 1196: 1187: 1181: 1180: 1174: 1173: 1158: 1152: 1145: 1139: 1138: 1136: 1135: 1125: 1116: 1110: 1104: 1098: 1093: 1087: 1082: 1076: 1075: 1073: 1062: 1053: 1047: 1042: 1004:Northern Ireland 990:Replacement list 960:Special election 883:Condorcet method 875:Condorcet winner 673:Cork Corporation 540:malapportionment 519:resulted in the 452:was introduced. 395:Northern Ireland 347:Electoral stasis 272:directly elected 263: 256: 252: 249: 243: 212: 204: 186:British Columbia 182:plurality voting 157: 137: 136: 129: 122: 115: 111: 108: 102: 100: 59: 35: 27: 21: 1551: 1550: 1546: 1545: 1544: 1542: 1541: 1540: 1526: 1525: 1524: 1523: 1517:Wayback Machine 1508: 1504: 1498:Wayback Machine 1489: 1485: 1479:Wayback Machine 1470: 1466: 1450: 1449: 1443: 1441: 1437: 1430: 1428:"Archived copy" 1426: 1420: 1416: 1408: 1404: 1396: 1392: 1384: 1380: 1371: 1367: 1357: 1355: 1344: 1343: 1339: 1325: 1323: 1312: 1308: 1301: 1297: 1288: 1284: 1267: 1266: 1260: 1258: 1254: 1241: 1239:"Archived copy" 1237: 1235: 1231: 1214: 1213: 1207: 1205: 1201: 1194: 1192:"Archived copy" 1190: 1188: 1184: 1171: 1169: 1159: 1155: 1147:Maltadata.com. 1146: 1142: 1133: 1131: 1123: 1117: 1113: 1105: 1101: 1094: 1090: 1083: 1079: 1071: 1060: 1054: 1050: 1043: 1039: 1034: 1012: 992: 962: 956: 951: 945: 920: 911: 858:Alabama paradox 817: 812: 810:Vote management 806: 776: 700: 698:Tactical voting 615:Binomial System 596: 585:political party 509: 507:Proportionality 466: 375: 349: 264: 253: 247: 244: 229: 213: 202: 178: 162: 138: 134: 123: 112: 106: 103: 60: 58: 48: 36: 23: 22: 15: 12: 11: 5: 1549: 1539: 1538: 1522: 1521: 1502: 1483: 1464: 1414: 1402: 1390: 1378: 1365: 1337: 1306: 1295: 1282: 1229: 1182: 1167:www.aph.gov.au 1153: 1140: 1128:Voting Matters 1111: 1099: 1088: 1077: 1048: 1036: 1035: 1033: 1030: 1029: 1028: 1023: 1018: 1011: 1008: 998:, a departing 991: 988: 970:instant-runoff 958:Main article: 955: 952: 947:Main article: 944: 941: 919: 916: 910: 907: 841:spoiler effect 816: 813: 808:Main article: 805: 802: 775: 772: 752: 751: 748: 745: 742: 739: 732: 731: 724: 699: 696: 651:gerrymandering 595: 592: 508: 505: 500:"four As" ploy 478:, a Tasmanian 465: 462: 374: 371: 348: 345: 266: 265: 216: 214: 207: 201: 198: 177: 174: 164: 163: 141: 139: 132: 125: 124: 39: 37: 30: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 1548: 1537: 1534: 1533: 1531: 1518: 1514: 1511: 1506: 1499: 1495: 1492: 1487: 1480: 1476: 1473: 1468: 1460: 1454: 1440:on 2007-07-01 1436: 1429: 1424: 1418: 1411: 1406: 1399: 1394: 1387: 1382: 1375: 1369: 1353: 1352: 1347: 1341: 1334: 1321: 1317: 1310: 1304: 1299: 1292: 1286: 1277: 1271: 1257:on 2012-01-18 1253: 1249: 1248: 1240: 1233: 1224: 1218: 1204:on 2011-05-18 1200: 1193: 1186: 1179: 1168: 1164: 1157: 1150: 1144: 1129: 1122: 1115: 1109: 1103: 1097: 1092: 1086: 1081: 1074:on 2011-07-26 1070: 1066: 1059: 1052: 1046: 1041: 1037: 1027: 1024: 1022: 1019: 1017: 1014: 1013: 1007: 1005: 1001: 997: 987: 985: 980: 976: 971: 968:(effectively 967: 961: 950: 940: 938: 933: 930: 926: 915: 906: 904: 899: 897: 893: 889: 884: 880: 876: 870: 867: 863: 859: 854: 852: 851:on the ballot 847: 842: 838: 834: 830: 826: 822: 811: 801: 799: 795: 790: 786: 781: 771: 767: 763: 760: 756: 749: 746: 743: 740: 737: 736: 735: 729: 725: 722: 718: 717: 716: 712: 709: 708:deterministic 705: 695: 691: 689: 684: 682: 678: 674: 669: 665: 663: 658: 654: 652: 647: 645: 640: 637: 635: 630: 626: 624: 620: 616: 610: 607: 603: 601: 594:District size 591: 590: 586: 582: 577: 573: 571: 567: 563: 558: 556: 552: 547: 545: 541: 536: 534: 530: 526: 522: 518: 513: 504: 501: 495: 492: 488: 485:In the Irish 483: 481: 477: 472: 461: 459: 453: 451: 447: 446:Nick Xenophon 443: 438: 434: 429: 427: 423: 422:donkey voting 418: 416: 412: 407: 404: 400: 396: 392: 388: 379: 373:Ballot design 370: 366: 363: 359: 353: 344: 342: 337: 332: 326: 324: 320: 316: 311: 309: 305: 299: 297: 293: 289: 284: 282: 278: 273: 262: 259: 251: 241: 237: 233: 227: 226: 222: 217:This section 215: 211: 206: 205: 197: 193: 191: 187: 183: 173: 171: 160: 155: 151: 150: 145: 140: 131: 130: 121: 118: 110: 99: 96: 92: 89: 85: 82: 78: 75: 71: 68: â€“  67: 63: 62:Find sources: 56: 52: 46: 45: 40:This article 38: 34: 29: 28: 19: 1505: 1486: 1467: 1442:. Retrieved 1435:the original 1422: 1417: 1405: 1393: 1381: 1368: 1356:. Retrieved 1349: 1340: 1331: 1324:. Retrieved 1319: 1309: 1298: 1285: 1259:. Retrieved 1252:the original 1245: 1232: 1206:. Retrieved 1199:the original 1185: 1176: 1170:. Retrieved 1166: 1156: 1143: 1132:. Retrieved 1127: 1114: 1102: 1091: 1080: 1069:the original 1064: 1051: 1040: 993: 977:and for the 963: 934: 921: 912: 900: 871: 855: 850: 833:monotonicity 818: 789:Dublin North 777: 768: 764: 761: 757: 753: 733: 713: 701: 692: 685: 670: 666: 659: 655: 648: 641: 638: 631: 627: 611: 608: 604: 597: 580: 578: 574: 566:WA Nationals 559: 548: 537: 521:Labour Party 514: 510: 496: 484: 467: 454: 430: 419: 408: 384: 367: 354: 350: 327: 312: 300: 288:trade unions 285: 277:partisanship 269: 254: 248:October 2014 245: 230:Please help 218: 194: 179: 167: 158: 147: 113: 107:October 2023 104: 94: 87: 80: 73: 61: 49:Please help 44:verification 41: 1425:24:2. Also 1374:Free riding 1358:17 December 1326:17 December 1130:(21): 12–15 1106:Oireachtas 1026:Schulze STV 966:by-election 954:By-election 918:Appointment 903:Borda count 476:Neil Robson 409:To prevent 358:Territories 313:Successful 281:party lists 1444:2007-07-26 1261:2010-11-20 1208:2010-11-20 1172:2020-10-27 1134:2017-04-08 1032:References 369:election. 176:Complexity 77:newspapers 1333:selected. 949:Countback 943:Countback 937:co-option 909:Vacancies 798:factorial 600:districts 219:does not 1530:Category 1513:Archived 1494:Archived 1475:Archived 1453:cite web 1270:cite web 1217:cite web 1010:See also 555:Victoria 471:surnames 426:Tasmania 417:vote). 315:campaign 1016:CPO-STV 892:CPO-STV 741:90: B 662:NP-hard 360:in the 296:schools 240:removed 225:sources 154:Discuss 91:scholar 1247:RTÉ.ie 979:Seanad 728:BC-STV 570:Greens 474:after 415:Langer 294:, and 190:BC-STV 144:merged 93:  86:  79:  72:  64:  1438:(PDF) 1431:(PDF) 1255:(PDF) 1242:(PDF) 1202:(PDF) 1195:(PDF) 1124:(PDF) 1072:(PDF) 1061:(PDF) 721:ERS97 292:clubs 146:into 98:JSTOR 84:books 1459:link 1400:2004 1360:2013 1328:2013 1276:link 1223:link 975:Dáil 644:1996 634:1923 560:The 491:Dáil 487:Dáil 393:and 341:Dáil 223:any 221:cite 70:news 1002:or 480:MHA 234:by 152:. ( 53:by 1532:: 1455:}} 1451:{{ 1376:". 1348:. 1330:. 1318:. 1272:}} 1268:{{ 1244:. 1227:"] 1219:}} 1215:{{ 1175:. 1165:. 1126:. 1063:, 898:. 853:. 683:. 572:. 298:. 290:, 1461:) 1447:. 1362:. 1280:" 1278:) 1264:. 1225:) 1211:. 1137:. 261:) 255:( 250:) 246:( 242:. 228:. 156:) 120:) 114:( 109:) 105:( 95:· 88:· 81:· 74:· 47:. 20:)

Index

Countback (single transferable vote)

verification
improve this article
adding citations to reliable sources
"Issues affecting the single transferable vote"
news
newspapers
books
scholar
JSTOR
Learn how and when to remove this message
merged
Single transferable vote
Discuss
single transferable vote
plurality voting
British Columbia
BC-STV

cite
sources
improve this section
adding citations to reliable sources
removed
Learn how and when to remove this message
directly elected
partisanship
party lists
trade unions

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑