Knowledge

Tying (commerce)

Source 📝

731:
to determine whether the dominant undertaking tied two distinct products. This is important as two identical products cannot be considered tied under Article 102(2)(d) formulation that states products will be considered tied if they have no connects ‘by their nature or commercial usage’. This arises problems in the legal definition of what will amount to tying in scenarios of selling cars with tires or selling a car with a radio. Hence, the Commission provides guidance on this issue by citing the judgement in Microsoft and states that "two products are distinct if, in the absence of tying or bundling, a substantial number of customers would purchase or would have purchased the tying product without also buying the tied product from the same supplier, thereby allowing stand-alone production for both the tying and the tied product". Next issue is whether the customer was coerced to purchase both the tying and the tied products as Article 102(2)(d) suggests: ‘making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations’. In situations of contractual stipulation, it is clear that the test will be satisfied; for an example of a non-contractual tying see Microsoft. Furthermore, for an undertaking to be deemed anti-competitive is whether the tie is capable of having foreclosure effect. Some examples of tying practices having an anti-competitive foreclosure effect in case law are the IBM, Eurofix-Bauco v Hilti, Telemarketing v CLT, British Sugar and Microsoft. Subsequently, the defence available for the dominant undertaking is that it can provide that tying is objectively justified or enhances efficiency and the commission is willing to consider claims that are tying may result in economic efficiency in production or distribution that will bring benefit to the consumers.
722:
until the buyer agrees to purchase both products, withdrawal or withholding of a guarantee where the dominant seller will not provide the benefit of guarantee until the seller accepts to purchase that party's product, technical tying occurs when the products of the dominant party are physically integrated and making impossible to buy the one without the other and bundling where two products are sold in the same package with one price. These practises are prohibited under Article 101(1)(e) and Article 102(2)(d) and may amount to an infringement of the statute if other conditions are satisfied. However, it is noteworthy that the Court is willing to find an infringement beyond those listed in Article 102(2)(d), see Tetra Pak v Commission.
482:. A tying arrangement is defined as "an agreement by a party to sell one product but only on the condition that the buyer also purchases a different (or tied) product, or at least agrees he will not purchase the product from any other supplier." Tying may be the action of several companies as well as the work of just one firm. Success on a tying claim typically requires proof of four elements: (1) two separate products or services are involved; (2) the purchase of the tying product is conditioned on the additional purchase of the tied product; (3) the seller has sufficient market power in the market for the tying product; (4) a not insubstantial amount of interstate commerce in the tied product market is affected. 493:, going so far as to hold that possession of a copyright or even the existence of a tie itself gave rise to a presumption of economic power. The Supreme Court has since held that a plaintiff must establish the sort of market power necessary for other antitrust violations in order to prove sufficient "economic power" necessary to establish a per se tie. More recently, the Court has eliminated any presumption of market power based solely on the fact that the tying product is patented or copyrighted. 693:(BHCA), the anti-tying provision, which is codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1972. The statute was designed to prevent banks, whether large or small, state or federal, from imposing anticompetitive conditions on their customers. Tying is an antitrust violation, but the Sherman and Clayton Acts did not adequately protect borrowers from being required to accept conditions to loans issued by banks, and section 106 was specifically designed to apply to and remedy such bank misconduct. 22: 91: 538:, any user who tried to unlock or otherwise tamper with the locking software ran the risk of rendering their iPhone permanently inoperable. This caused complaints among many consumers, as they were forced to pay an additional early termination fee of $ 175 if they wanted to unlock the device safely for use on a different carrier. Other companies such as 658:") were charged less for their Windows bulk purchases if they agreed to bundle Office with every PC sold than if they gave computer purchasers the choice whether or not to buy Office along with their machines — making their computer prices less competitive in the market. The Novell litigation has since settled. 405:: people who use more razor blades, for example, pay more than those who just need a one-time shave. Though this may improve overall welfare, by giving more consumers access to the market, such price discrimination can also transfer consumer surpluses to the producer. Tying may also be used with or in place of 457:
is the practice of requiring customers to purchase related products or services together, from the same company. For example, a company might mandate that its automobiles could only be serviced by its own dealers. In an effort to curb this, many jurisdictions require that warranties not be voided by
730:
The Guidance on Article 102 Enforcement Priorities sets out in which circumstances it will be appropriate taking actions against tying practices. First, it must be established whether the accused undertaking has a dominant position in the tying or tied product market. Subsequently, the next step is
721:
Tying is the "practice of a supplier of one product, the tying product, requiring a buyer also to buy a second product, the tied product". The tying of a product can take various forms, that of contractual tying where a contract binds the buyer to purchase both products together, refusal to supply
712:
oversee the activities of banks, their holding companies, and other related depository institutions. While each type of depository institution has a “primary regulator”, the nation's “dual banking” system allows concurrent jurisdiction among the different regulatory agencies. With respect to the
567:
that is protected by copyright law. This means that the license on the operating system forbids software modification. However, regulators agreed that modifying an iPhone's firmware/operating system to enable it to run an application that Apple has not approved fits comfortably within the four
562:
or hardware restrictions imposed on an iPhone (or other device). If done successfully, this allows one to run any application on the phone they choose, including applications not authorized by Apple. Apple told regulators that modifying the iPhone operating system leads to the creation of an
614:, making IE difficult to remove from Windows 98 (e.g., not putting it on the "Remove Programs" list), and designing Windows 98 to work "unpleasantly" with Netscape Navigator constituted an illegal tying of Windows 98 and IE. Microsoft's counterargument was that a 553:
In July 2010, federal regulators clarified the issue when they determined it was lawful to unlock (or in other terms, "jail break") the iPhone, declaring that there was no basis for copyright law to assist Apple in protecting its restrictive business model.
713:
anti-tying provision, the Fed takes the preeminent role in relation to the other financial institution regulatory agencies, which reflects that it was considered the least biased (in favor of banks) of the regulatory agencies when section 106 was enacted.
390:. The basic idea is that consumers are harmed by being forced to buy an undesired good (the tied good) in order to purchase a good they actually want (the tying good), and so would prefer that the goods be sold separately. The company doing this 550:. The suit was filed by the Law Office of Damian R. Fernandez on behalf of California resident Timothy P. Smith, and ultimately sought to have an injunction issued against Apple to prevent it from selling iPhones with any kind of software lock. 394:
may have a significantly large market share so that it may impose the tie on consumers, despite the forces of market competition. The tie may also harm other companies in the market for the tied good, or who sell only single components.
696:
Banks are allowed to take measures to protect their loans and to safeguard the value of their investments, such as requiring security or guaranties from borrowers. The statute exempts so-called “traditional banking practices” from its
416:
Tying is often used when the supplier makes one product that is critical to many customers. By threatening to withhold that key product unless others are also purchased, the supplier can increase sales of less necessary products.
638:
rejected Microsoft's claim that Internet Explorer was simply one facet of its operating system, but the court held that the tie between Windows and Internet Explorer should be analyzed deferentially under the
690: 496:
In recent years, changing business practices surrounding new technologies have put the legality of tying arrangements to the test. Although the Supreme Court still considers some tying arrangements as
705:
are denied. Banks still have quite a bit of leeway in fashioning loan agreements, but when a bank clearly steps over the bounds of propriety, the plaintiff is compensated with treble damages.
701:
illegality, and thus its purpose is not so much to limit banks' lending practices, as it is to ensure that the practices used are fair and competitive. A majority of claims brought under the
635: 1315: 1498:
Case C-311/84 Centre belge d'études de marché - Télémarketing (CBEM) v SA Compagnie luxembourgeoise de télédiffusion (CLT) and Information publicité Benelux (IPB) ECLI:EU:C:1985:394
650:
included a claim for harm in the market for office productivity applications. The Attorneys General abandoned this claim when filing an amended complaint. The claim was revived by
153: 500:
illegal, the Court actually uses a rule-of-reason analysis, requiring an analysis of foreclosure effects and an affirmative defense of efficiency justifications.
433: 1081: 1056: 379:, a common (and legal) method of giving away (or selling at a substantial discount) one item to ensure a continual flow of sales of another related item. 1223: 1452: 542:
complained that tying encourages a more closed-access-based wireless service. Many questioned the legality of the arrangement, and in October 2007 a
447:
is the practice of requiring consumers to pay for an unrelated product or service together with the desired one. A hypothetical example would be for
351:) is the practice of selling one product or service as a mandatory addition to the purchase of a different product or service. In legal terms, a 32: 1340: 331: 1249: 451:
to sell its pens only with Bic lighters. (However, a company may offer a limited free item with another purchase as a promotion.)
836: 634:
and radios, Microsoft claimed the definition of an operating system has changed to include their formerly separate products. The
1696: 1300: 1277:
Timothy D. Naegele, The Bank Holding Company Act's Anti-Tying Provision: 35 Years Later, 122 Banking Law Journal 195 (2005);
523: 509: 1681: 1345:. Vol. 26. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1997. 1997. pp. 48–49. 1462: 1350: 972: 398:
One effect of tying can be that low quality products achieve a higher market share than would otherwise be the case.
300: 66: 1657:
Christopher Leslie, Cutting Through Tying Theory with Occam's Razor: A Simple Explanation of Tying Arrangements, 78
1416: 626:
operating systems, and the integration of the products was technologically justified. Just as the definition of a
518:
products is an example of commercial tying that has caused recent controversy. When Apple initially released the
1109: 930: 807: 1200:
See Complaint filed in New York v. Microsoft Corp. PP 88-95, 98, 117-19, No. 98-1233 (D.D.C. filed May 18, 1998)
785: 138: 1622:
Christopher Leslie, Unilaterally Imposed Tying Arrangements and Antitrust's Concerted Action Requirement, 60
324: 243: 1519: 1438: 1404: 1392: 1457:. Vol. 14. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities. pp. 77–79. 1381: 375:). Tying is often illegal when the products are not naturally related. It is related to but distinct from 1508: 1486: 1327: 1144: 1175: 582: 459: 429: 387: 172: 107: 1497: 780: 1691: 1686: 1580:
Richard Craswell, Tying Requirements in Competitive Markets: The Consumer Protection Rationale, 62
1001: 534:
that ensured the phone would not work on any network besides AT&T's. Related to the concept of
317: 48: 1650:
Michael D. Whinston, Exclusivity and Tying in U.S. v. Microsoft: What We Know, and Don't Know, 15
1552:
Kenneth Dam, Fortner Enterprises v. United States Steel: Neither a Borrower Nor A Lender Be, 1969
1291:
Whish, Richard; Bailey, David (2018). "Chapter 17 Abuse of Dominance (1): non-pricing practices".
1615:
Alan Meese, Tying Meets The New Institutional Economics: Farewell to the Chimera of Forcing, 146
702: 674: 546:
was filed against Apple, claiming that its exclusive agreement with AT&T violates California
1224:"Microsoft Inside: 20 New Android Device Manufacturers Sign-on to Pre-Install Office and Skype" 647: 217: 1643:
Keith N. Hylton and Michael Salinger, Tying Law and Policy: A Decision-Theoretic Approach, 69
1057:"Does Apple's Tightly Controlled Ecosystem Strategy Constitute and Illegal Tying Arrangement?" 1664:
Timothy D. Naegele, The Bank Holding Company Act's Anti-Tying Provision: 35 Years Later, 122
1629:
John Lopatka and William Page, The Dubious Search For Integration in the Microsoft Trial, 31
1573:
Joseph Bauer, A Simplified Approach to Tying Arrangements: A Legal and Economic Analysis, 33
709: 475: 305: 44: 944: 599: 543: 402: 260: 255: 143: 40: 8: 490: 1636:
Alan Meese, Monopoly Bundling in Cyberspace: How Many Products Does Microsoft Sell?, 44
530:) contracts in the United States. To enforce this exclusivity, Apple employed a type of 1608:
Benjamin Klein and Lester Saft, The Law and Economics of Franchise Tying Contracts, 28
740: 279: 201: 1451:
European Commission (1985). "6 — Article 86 applied to abuse of a dominant position".
1427: 1370: 1468: 1458: 1346: 1296: 623: 595: 591: 376: 265: 250: 133: 121: 610:. The United States claimed that the bundling of Internet Explorer (IE) to sales of 1149: 1030: 770: 765: 619: 607: 559: 555: 448: 428:
have laws against tying, which are enforced by state governments. In addition, the
391: 356: 274: 224: 126: 1601:
Victor Kramer, The Supreme Court and Tying Arrangements: Antitrust As History, 69
1278: 1114: 603: 564: 531: 233: 212: 158: 82: 1594:
Timothy D. Naegele, The Anti-Tying Provision: Its Potential Is Still There, 100
775: 640: 486: 181: 163: 931:
https://www.criterioneconomics.com/docs/do-free-mobile-apps-harm-consumers.pdf
1675: 1472: 1250:"Xiaomi will bundle Microsoft's Office and Skype apps on its Android devices" 841: 547: 471: 421: 270: 238: 1086: 284: 197: 148: 1082:"California man seeks class action lawsuit over iPhone bricking, lock-in" 750: 631: 630:
has changed to include things that used to be separate products, such as
615: 479: 207: 371:
customer) conditional on the purchase of a second distinctive good (the
1535: 758:
or 'Hackintosh', breaking the tie Apple holds between its hardware and
684: 670: 662: 646:
As to the tying of Office, parallel cases against Microsoft brought by
643:. The U.S. government claim settled before reaching final resolution. 611: 515: 425: 1110:"Apple Class-Action Suit Filed by California Man Over iPhone Bricking" 1587:
Roy Kenney and Benjamin Klein, The Economics of Block Booking, 26 J.
1034: 587: 410: 186: 116: 90: 485:
For at least three decades, the Supreme Court defined the required "
949: 759: 636:
United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit
569: 535: 527: 383: 364: 112: 1316:
Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union
1145:"U.S. Declares iPhone Jailbreaking Legal, Over Apple's Objections" 1428:
Case T-201/04 Microsoft Corp v Commission EU:T:2007:289, para 963
745: 665:
mobile operating system, by requiring manufacturers that license
368: 510:
History of iPhone § Exclusivity tying of iPhone to AT&T
666: 651: 539: 519: 406: 192: 413:
to help protect entry into a market, discouraging innovation.
755: 678: 31:
deal primarily with the United States and do not represent a
976: 655: 627: 1509:
Case No IV/30.178 Napier Brown-British Sugar OJ L284/41
1382:
C-333/94 P Tetra Pak v Commission EU:C:1996:436,para 37
1215: 863:
N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5-6 (1958)
661:
Microsoft has also tied its software to the third-party
1559:
Timothy D. Naegele, Are All Bank Tie-Ins Illegal?, 154
1371:
Case T-201/04 Microsoft Corp v Commission EU:T:2007:289
1024: 1022: 1487:
IV/30.787 and 31.488 - Eurofix-Bauco v. Hilti L 65/19
1031:"Democrats criticize AT&T's exclusive iPhone deal" 1075: 1073: 654:
where they alleged that manufacturers of computers ("
1295:(9 ed.). Oxford University Press. p. 705. 1019: 902:
See Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde
685:
Anti-tying provision of the Bank Holding Company Act
1450: 580:Another prominent case involving a tying claim was 1520:The Guidance on Article 102 Enforcement Priorities 1439:The Guidance on Article 102 Enforcement Priorities 1405:The Guidance on Article 102 Enforcement Priorities 1393:The Guidance on Article 102 Enforcement Priorities 1366: 1364: 1362: 1070: 995: 993: 762:to run the operating system on non-Apple hardware. 1545:George J. Stigler, A Note On Block Booking, 1963 1054: 874:Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc. 725: 1673: 1107: 929:, 52 SAN DIEGO L. REV. (forthcoming Aug. 2015), 708:At least four regulatory agencies including the 432:enforces federal laws against tying through its 1359: 1138: 1136: 1134: 1132: 1079: 990: 1279:http://www.naegele.com/whats_new.html#articles 1242: 1142: 886:See Fornter Enterprises v. United States Steel 470:Certain tying arrangements are illegal in the 999: 942: 689:In 1970, Congress enacted section 106 of the 325: 29:The examples and perspective in this article 1129: 1536:Tying Arrangements Under the Antitrust Laws 1290: 1169: 1167: 964: 802: 800: 691:Bank Holding Company Act Amendments of 1970 489:" to include just about any departure from 1342:European Community competition policy 1996 914:See Illinois Tool Works v. Independent Ink 332: 318: 293:Enforcement authorities and organizations 67:Learn how and when to remove this message 1164: 797: 618:and a mail reader are simply part of an 458:outside servicing; for example, see the 1454:Fourteenth Report on Competition Policy 1028: 837:International Salt Co. v. United States 465: 1674: 970: 575: 386:, have historically been regarded as 1108:Wolfe, Alexander (October 5, 2007). 1000:Hafner, Katie (September 29, 2007). 15: 1080:Chartier, David (October 7, 2007). 973:"How Apple kept its iPhone secrets" 927:Do Free Mobile Apps Harm Consumers? 382:Some kinds of tying, especially by 13: 1568:Antitrust: An Economic Perspective 1055:Gonsowski, Laurie (July 6, 2007). 716: 89: 14: 1708: 1417:Case COMP/39230 – Rio Tinto Alcan 1328:Eurofix-Bauci v Hilti OJ L 65/19 1221: 971:Lewis, Peter (January 12, 2007). 943:Honan, Mathew (January 9, 2007). 503: 301:International Competition Network 1652:Journal of Economic Perspectives 1143:Kravets, David (July 26, 2010). 20: 1528: 1513: 1502: 1491: 1480: 1444: 1432: 1421: 1410: 1398: 1386: 1375: 1332: 1321: 1309: 1284: 1268: 1203: 1194: 1182: 1178:, 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001). 1101: 1048: 1029:Broache, Anne (July 11, 2007). 936: 832:N. Pac. Ry Co. v. United States 786:Tying of the iPhone to AT&T 430:U.S. Department of Justice 919: 907: 895: 879: 867: 856: 847: 822: 726:Enforcement under European Law 524:sold exclusively with AT&T 306:List of competition regulators 1: 876:, 504 U.S. 451, 461–62 (1992) 791: 681:applications on the devices. 1697:Bundled products or services 890:United States v. Loew's, Inc 669:it claims covers the OS and 401:Tying may also be a form of 7: 1002:"Altered iPhones Freeze Up" 734: 43:, discuss the issue on the 10: 1713: 1682:Anti-competitive practices 1176:United States v. Microsoft 583:United States v. Microsoft 507: 460:Magnuson-Moss Warranty Act 388:anti-competitive practices 173:Anti-competitive practices 139:Herfindahl–Hirschman index 108:History of competition law 781:Digital rights management 522:on June 29, 2007, it was 1582:Boston University L. Rev 439: 888:, 394 U.S. 495 (1969); 675:Microsoft Office Mobile 648:State Attorneys General 478:, and Section 3 of the 1339:"C-New Developments". 1212:Civil No. JFM-05-1087. 945:"Apple unveils iPhone" 622:, included with other 462:in the United States. 355:makes the sale of one 218:Occupational licensing 94: 1575:Vanderbilt Law Review 1228:SuperSite for Windows 834:, 356 U.S. 1 (1958); 810:. The Blanch Law Firm 710:Federal Reserve Board 476:Sherman Antitrust Act 93: 1610:J. Law and Economics 1547:Supreme Court Review 916:, 547 U.S. 28 (2006) 892:. 372 U.S. 38 (1962) 600:Windows Media Player 586:. By some accounts, 544:class-action lawsuit 466:In United States law 403:price discrimination 261:Occupational closure 256:Dividing territories 244:Essential facilities 144:Market concentration 49:create a new article 41:improve this article 1666:Banking Law Journal 1596:Banking Law Journal 1589:Law & Economics 1566:Richard A. Posner, 904:, 466 U.S. 2 (1985) 491:perfect competition 1441:, Footnotes 52-58. 1006:The New York Times 925:J. Gregory Sidak, 741:Complementary good 576:Microsoft products 434:Antitrust Division 280:Regulatory capture 95: 1603:Minnesota L. Rev. 1302:978-0-19-877906-3 756:The OSx86 Project 624:personal computer 596:Internet Explorer 592:Microsoft Windows 377:freebie marketing 342: 341: 271:Misuse of patents 266:Predatory pricing 251:Exclusive dealing 134:Barriers to entry 122:Coercive monopoly 77: 76: 69: 51:, as appropriate. 1704: 1570:, 171-84 (1976); 1561:Bankers Magazine 1523: 1517: 1511: 1506: 1500: 1495: 1489: 1484: 1478: 1476: 1448: 1442: 1436: 1430: 1425: 1419: 1414: 1408: 1402: 1396: 1390: 1384: 1379: 1373: 1368: 1357: 1356: 1336: 1330: 1325: 1319: 1313: 1307: 1306: 1288: 1282: 1272: 1266: 1265: 1263: 1261: 1246: 1240: 1239: 1237: 1235: 1219: 1213: 1207: 1201: 1198: 1192: 1191:at 64-67, 84-86. 1186: 1180: 1171: 1162: 1161: 1159: 1157: 1140: 1127: 1126: 1124: 1122: 1105: 1099: 1098: 1096: 1094: 1077: 1068: 1067: 1065: 1063: 1052: 1046: 1045: 1043: 1041: 1026: 1017: 1016: 1014: 1012: 997: 988: 987: 985: 983: 968: 962: 961: 959: 957: 940: 934: 923: 917: 911: 905: 899: 893: 883: 877: 871: 865: 860: 854: 851: 845: 826: 820: 819: 817: 815: 804: 771:Product churning 766:Product bundling 620:operating system 608:Microsoft Office 560:operating system 445:Horizontal tying 334: 327: 320: 225:Product bundling 127:Natural monopoly 79: 78: 72: 65: 61: 58: 52: 24: 23: 16: 1712: 1711: 1707: 1706: 1705: 1703: 1702: 1701: 1692:Business models 1687:Competition law 1672: 1671: 1661:727 (2004); and 1654:, 63-80 (2001); 1645:Antitrust L. J. 1638:Antitrust Bull. 1617:U. Penn. L. Rev 1534:Donald Turner, 1531: 1526: 1518: 1514: 1507: 1503: 1496: 1492: 1485: 1481: 1465: 1449: 1445: 1437: 1433: 1426: 1422: 1415: 1411: 1403: 1399: 1391: 1387: 1380: 1376: 1369: 1360: 1353: 1338: 1337: 1333: 1326: 1322: 1314: 1310: 1303: 1293:Competition Law 1289: 1285: 1273: 1269: 1259: 1257: 1248: 1247: 1243: 1233: 1231: 1220: 1216: 1208: 1204: 1199: 1195: 1187: 1183: 1172: 1165: 1155: 1153: 1141: 1130: 1120: 1118: 1115:InformationWeek 1106: 1102: 1092: 1090: 1078: 1071: 1061: 1059: 1053: 1049: 1039: 1037: 1027: 1020: 1010: 1008: 998: 991: 981: 979: 969: 965: 955: 953: 941: 937: 924: 920: 912: 908: 900: 896: 884: 880: 872: 868: 861: 857: 853:15 U.S.C. s. 14 852: 848: 827: 823: 813: 811: 806: 805: 798: 794: 737: 728: 719: 717:In European Law 687: 604:Outlook Express 578: 565:derivative work 512: 506: 474:under both the 468: 442: 338: 234:Refusal to deal 213:Tacit collusion 159:Relevant market 83:Competition law 73: 62: 56: 53: 38: 25: 21: 12: 11: 5: 1710: 1700: 1699: 1694: 1689: 1684: 1670: 1669: 1662: 1655: 1648: 1641: 1634: 1627: 1620: 1613: 1606: 1599: 1592: 1585: 1578: 1571: 1564: 1557: 1550: 1543: 1530: 1527: 1525: 1524: 1522:, Footnote 62. 1512: 1501: 1490: 1479: 1477:, points 94-95 1463: 1443: 1431: 1420: 1409: 1407:, Footnote 51. 1397: 1395:, Footnote 34. 1385: 1374: 1358: 1351: 1331: 1320: 1308: 1301: 1283: 1267: 1241: 1214: 1202: 1193: 1181: 1163: 1128: 1100: 1069: 1047: 1018: 989: 963: 935: 918: 906: 894: 878: 866: 855: 846: 821: 795: 793: 790: 789: 788: 783: 778: 776:Vendor lock-in 773: 768: 763: 753: 748: 743: 736: 733: 727: 724: 718: 715: 686: 683: 641:Rule of Reason 590:ties together 577: 574: 508:Main article: 505: 504:Apple products 502: 487:economic power 467: 464: 455:Vertical tying 441: 438: 340: 339: 337: 336: 329: 322: 314: 311: 310: 309: 308: 303: 295: 294: 290: 289: 288: 287: 282: 277: 268: 263: 258: 253: 248: 247: 246: 241: 231: 222: 221: 220: 215: 210: 205: 195: 184: 182:Monopolization 176: 175: 169: 168: 167: 166: 164:Merger control 161: 156: 151: 146: 141: 136: 131: 130: 129: 124: 110: 102: 101: 100:Basic concepts 97: 96: 86: 85: 75: 74: 35:of the subject 33:worldwide view 28: 26: 19: 9: 6: 4: 3: 2: 1709: 1698: 1695: 1693: 1690: 1688: 1685: 1683: 1680: 1679: 1677: 1667: 1663: 1660: 1656: 1653: 1649: 1646: 1642: 1639: 1635: 1632: 1631:Conn. L. Rev. 1628: 1625: 1624:Ohio St. L.J. 1621: 1618: 1614: 1611: 1607: 1604: 1600: 1597: 1593: 1590: 1586: 1584:. 661 (1982); 1583: 1579: 1576: 1572: 1569: 1565: 1562: 1558: 1555: 1551: 1548: 1544: 1541: 1537: 1533: 1532: 1521: 1516: 1510: 1505: 1499: 1494: 1488: 1483: 1474: 1470: 1466: 1464:92-825-4872-4 1460: 1456: 1455: 1447: 1440: 1435: 1429: 1424: 1418: 1413: 1406: 1401: 1394: 1389: 1383: 1378: 1372: 1367: 1365: 1363: 1354: 1352:92-828-0298-1 1348: 1344: 1343: 1335: 1329: 1324: 1317: 1312: 1304: 1298: 1294: 1287: 1280: 1276: 1271: 1255: 1251: 1245: 1229: 1225: 1218: 1211: 1206: 1197: 1190: 1185: 1179: 1177: 1170: 1168: 1152: 1151: 1146: 1139: 1137: 1135: 1133: 1117: 1116: 1111: 1104: 1089: 1088: 1083: 1076: 1074: 1058: 1051: 1036: 1032: 1025: 1023: 1007: 1003: 996: 994: 978: 974: 967: 952: 951: 946: 939: 932: 928: 922: 915: 910: 903: 898: 891: 887: 882: 875: 870: 864: 859: 850: 843: 839: 838: 833: 830: 825: 809: 803: 801: 796: 787: 784: 782: 779: 777: 774: 772: 769: 767: 764: 761: 757: 754: 752: 749: 747: 744: 742: 739: 738: 732: 723: 714: 711: 706: 704: 700: 694: 692: 682: 680: 676: 672: 668: 664: 659: 657: 653: 649: 644: 642: 637: 633: 629: 625: 621: 617: 613: 609: 605: 601: 597: 593: 589: 585: 584: 573: 571: 566: 561: 557: 556:Jail breaking 551: 549: 548:antitrust law 545: 541: 537: 533: 532:software lock 529: 525: 521: 517: 514:The tying of 511: 501: 499: 494: 492: 488: 483: 481: 477: 473: 472:United States 463: 461: 456: 452: 450: 446: 437: 435: 431: 427: 423: 422:United States 418: 414: 412: 408: 404: 399: 396: 393: 389: 385: 380: 378: 374: 370: 367:customer (or 366: 362: 358: 354: 350: 349:product tying 347:(informally, 346: 335: 330: 328: 323: 321: 316: 315: 313: 312: 307: 304: 302: 299: 298: 297: 296: 292: 291: 286: 283: 281: 278: 276: 272: 269: 267: 264: 262: 259: 257: 254: 252: 249: 245: 242: 240: 239:Group boycott 237: 236: 235: 232: 230: 226: 223: 219: 216: 214: 211: 209: 206: 203: 199: 196: 194: 191:Formation of 190: 189: 188: 185: 183: 180: 179: 178: 177: 174: 171: 170: 165: 162: 160: 157: 155: 152: 150: 147: 145: 142: 140: 137: 135: 132: 128: 125: 123: 120: 119: 118: 114: 111: 109: 106: 105: 104: 103: 99: 98: 92: 88: 87: 84: 81: 80: 71: 68: 60: 57:November 2012 50: 46: 42: 36: 34: 27: 18: 17: 1665: 1659:Tul. L. Rev. 1658: 1651: 1644: 1637: 1633:1251 (1999); 1630: 1626:1773 (1999); 1623: 1616: 1609: 1605:1013 (1985); 1602: 1595: 1588: 1581: 1574: 1567: 1560: 1553: 1546: 1542:. 50 (1958); 1540:Harv. L. Rev 1539: 1529:Bibliography 1515: 1504: 1493: 1482: 1453: 1446: 1434: 1423: 1412: 1400: 1388: 1377: 1341: 1334: 1323: 1311: 1292: 1286: 1274: 1270: 1258:. Retrieved 1253: 1244: 1232:. Retrieved 1227: 1222:Trent, Rod. 1217: 1209: 1205: 1196: 1188: 1184: 1173: 1154:. Retrieved 1148: 1119:. Retrieved 1113: 1103: 1091:. Retrieved 1087:Ars Technica 1085: 1060:. Retrieved 1050: 1038:. Retrieved 1009:. Retrieved 1005: 980:. Retrieved 966: 954:. Retrieved 948: 938: 926: 921: 913: 909: 901: 897: 889: 885: 881: 873: 869: 862: 858: 849: 842:332 U.S. 392 835: 831: 828: 824: 812:. Retrieved 729: 720: 707: 698: 695: 688: 660: 645: 632:speedometers 581: 579: 558:is removing 552: 513: 497: 495: 484: 469: 454: 453: 444: 443: 419: 415: 400: 397: 381: 372: 360: 352: 348: 344: 343: 285:Rent-seeking 228: 198:Price fixing 149:Market power 63: 54: 30: 1668:195 (2005). 1647:469 (2001); 1619:. 1 (1997); 1612:245 (1985); 1598:138 (1983); 1591:497 (1983); 1577:283 (1980); 1256:. June 2016 982:January 11, 751:Loss leader 671:smartphones 616:web browser 568:corners of 563:infringing 480:Clayton Act 208:Bid rigging 1676:Categories 1640:65 (1999); 1563:46 (1971); 1554:S. Ct. Rev 792:References 612:Windows 98 526:(formerly 411:copyrights 361:tying good 353:tying sale 275:copyrights 154:SSNIP test 1473:0259-3157 1318:, para.48 1260:23 August 1254:The Verge 1234:23 August 1156:March 15, 1121:March 15, 1093:March 15, 1062:March 15, 1040:March 14, 1035:CNET News 1011:March 15, 977:CNN Money 956:March 14, 588:Microsoft 373:tied good 363:) to the 187:Collusion 117:oligopoly 45:talk page 1230:. Penton 950:Macworld 814:31 March 760:Mac OS X 735:See also 673:to ship 570:fair use 536:bricking 528:Cingular 392:bundling 384:contract 365:de facto 113:Monopoly 39:You may 808:"Tying" 746:Iunctim 667:patents 663:Android 424:, most 420:In the 407:patents 369:de jure 193:cartels 1471:  1461:  1349:  1299:  844:(1947) 699:per se 652:Novell 540:Google 520:iPhone 498:per se 426:states 1538:, 72 1150:Wired 679:Skype 516:Apple 440:Types 359:(the 345:Tying 229:tying 202:cases 47:, or 1556:. 1; 1549:152; 1469:ISSN 1459:ISBN 1347:ISBN 1297:ISBN 1262:2016 1236:2016 1174:See 1158:2011 1123:2011 1095:2011 1064:2011 1042:2011 1013:2011 984:2009 958:2011 816:2011 703:BHCA 677:and 656:OEMs 606:and 357:good 273:and 227:and 115:and 1275:See 1210:See 1189:Id. 829:See 628:car 449:Bic 409:or 1678:: 1467:. 1361:^ 1252:. 1226:. 1166:^ 1147:. 1131:^ 1112:. 1084:. 1072:^ 1033:. 1021:^ 1004:. 992:^ 975:. 947:. 840:, 799:^ 602:, 598:, 594:, 572:. 436:. 1475:. 1355:. 1305:. 1281:. 1264:. 1238:. 1160:. 1125:. 1097:. 1066:. 1044:. 1015:. 986:. 960:. 933:. 818:. 333:e 326:t 319:v 204:) 200:( 70:) 64:( 59:) 55:( 37:.

Index

worldwide view
improve this article
talk page
create a new article
Learn how and when to remove this message
Competition law

History of competition law
Monopoly
oligopoly
Coercive monopoly
Natural monopoly
Barriers to entry
Herfindahl–Hirschman index
Market concentration
Market power
SSNIP test
Relevant market
Merger control
Anti-competitive practices
Monopolization
Collusion
cartels
Price fixing
cases
Bid rigging
Tacit collusion
Occupational licensing
Product bundling
tying

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License. Additional terms may apply.

↑